Front. Nutr. Frontiers in Nutrition Front. Nutr. 2296-861X Frontiers Media S.A. 10.3389/fnut.2025.1643753 Nutrition Original Research Ensuring a sustainable supply of aquatic products in the future: research on the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture Ma Ye 1 Zhang Ying 2 * 1School of Management, Ocean University of China, Qingdao, China 2School of Management, Ocean University of China, and the Institute of Marine Development, Ocean University of China, Qingdao, China

Edited by: Monika Thakur, Amity University, India

Reviewed by: Ratnakar Shukla, Sharda University, India

Chhavi Taliwal, Amity University, Noida, India

Deepak Mehta, Amity University, Noida, India

*Correspondence: Ying Zhang, yzhang@ouc.edu.cn
20 08 2025 2025 12 1643753 09 06 2025 28 07 2025 Copyright © 2025 Ma and Zhang. 2025 Ma and Zhang

This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.

Fisheries are an important source of protein for humans. Currently, freshwater and coastal aquaculture fisheries, as well as capture fisheries, have reached saturation point in terms of development potential and are severely polluted, making the supply of aquatic products unsustainable. Deep-sea aquaculture utilizes the vast exploitable space of the open sea, breaking through the limitations of coastal waters and land. It directly increases the global supply of high-protein aquatic products through large-scale and green aquaculture, playing an important role in ensuring the sustainable supply of aquatic products in the future and meeting human nutritional needs. Therefore, based on the assumptions of bounded rationality and stakeholder interdependence, this study constructed an evolutionary game model to analyze how to promote the application and implementation of deep-sea aquaculture. The conclusions of the study are as follows. First, this study affirms that the government plays an important role in promoting and applying deep-sea aquaculture, but government intervention cannot be sustained. Second, blind government intervention is not beneficial and may lead to a double failure of government and market. Finally, compared to the expected total profits from deep-sea aquaculture, it is more important to identify risk and cost thresholds and establish a fair mechanism for sharing benefits and risks. This threshold is defined as the total risk and costs should be less than the sum of potential profits and government subsidies. The research conclusions indicate that the government’s role in the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture should evolve in tandem with the industry’s maturity, transitioning from a “leading role in the initial phase” to a “guiding role in the mature phase.” Additionally, the fundamental approach to promoting the widespread adoption of deep-sea aquaculture lies in establishing a cooperative mechanism between aquaculture enterprise and service organization under the guidance of market mechanisms. This study aims to explore how to promote deep-sea aquaculture to enhance the sustainable supply of global aquatic products, thereby expanding and securing channels for human food and protein supply.

Graphical abstract

Flowchart illustrating the study on deep-sea aquaculture promotion. Starts with “Introduction” highlighting research background, literature review, and innovation. “Model construction and analysis” involves game models for aquaculture enterprises, service organizations, and government. “Simulation analysis” covers risk cost, cooperation benefit, and government intervention. Concludes with “Benefit sharing mechanism,” “Risk sharing mechanism,” and “Deep-sea aquaculture promotion,” emphasizing rational government intervention and cost reduction.

deep-sea aquaculture aquatic product supply evolutionary game model government intervention market mechanism section-at-acceptance Food Policy and Economics

香京julia种子在线播放

    1. <form id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv></nobr></form>
      <address id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv><nobr id=HxFbUHhlv></nobr></nobr></address>

      Introduction

      Deep-sea aquaculture refers to aquaculture activities conducted in offshore marine areas that are farther from the coast, have deeper water bodies, and more open environments. Currently, there is no unified or clear definition of deep-sea aquaculture. The Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO) defines Deep-sea aquaculture as an offshore production system that is set up in open sea areas exposed to wind and wave action, secured by facilities and equipment, and supported by supply vessels (1). The United States defines deep-sea aquaculture as a fishery farming industry outside the 12 nautical mile offshore and territorial sea, but within the country’s Exclusive Economic Zone, while Europe defines deep-sea aquaculture as a fishery farming industry that conducts its production activities in the high seas area (2). In China, it is defined as a large-scale deep-sea aquaculture method with large-scale fishery equipment as the main tool, supported by mechanization, intelligence, automation and other technologies (3).

      As the global population grows and living standards improve, the demand for high-quality animal proteins such as aquatic product continues to rise. By 2050, the global population is projected to exceed 9 billion people. Under current consumption levels, the demand for protein is expected to increase by over 20% (4). Fisheries play a crucial role in meeting human protein needs. According to statistics, the global fisheries production in 2020 reached 178 million tons, accounting for 17.5% of total protein supply (5). However, freshwater and coastal aquaculture capacity is now reaching saturation point, with extensive farming methods, excessive stocking densities, and overfishing leading to a sharp decline in natural fishery resources. Marine fishery ecological efficiency remains at a low level (6), posing challenges to the sustainability of the aquatic product supply system. Therefore, it is difficult for traditional fisheries to continue to meet the large aquatic consumption of the world’s population without sustainable transformation (7). Deep-sea aquaculture, on the one hand, can effectively increase the supply of aquatic product without occupying additional land resources, while utilizing more advanced aquaculture equipment and exerting less environmental pressure. It is currently the primary direction for the development of marine aquaculture (810). On the other hand, developing deep-sea aquaculture can effectively promote the concept of a “big food vision,” utilizing the superior water quality of distant sea areas to produce nutrient-rich marine fisheries (e.g., salmon), thereby expanding food supply channels and high-quality animal protein sources (1113). Based on this, this study aims to provide theoretical support and practical guidance for the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture from a game theory perspective by constructing a stakeholder game analysis model. By promoting the development and application of deep-sea aquaculture, this study further aims to ensure the sustainable supply of aquatic product.

      Research on deep-sea aquaculture has focussed firstly on top level design type studies. Based on the urgency of the current fishery transformation and the abundant advantages of deep-sea aquaculture, governments have made great efforts to promote the development of deep-sea aquaculture. The United States and Norway are the pioneer countries in the world in promoting the application of deep-sea aquaculture, and the deep-sea aquaculture technology of Atlantic salmon in Norway is very mature at present (14, 15), which mainly stems from the fact that the government has provided sufficient policy support for deep-sea aquaculture in terms of funding, technology, and industrial development (16, 17). In China, support for deep-sea aquaculture has been rising since 2011, and the number of relevant policies launched has been increasing, however, problems such as low efficiency of relevant policies, lack of articulation between policies, imperfect relevant supporting facilities, unbalanced policy support, and enterprise support to be improved have also been exposed (1820). Based on the existing problems, scholars have proposed measures to strengthen planning guidance (21), enhance demand-based policy formulation and promotion (22), promote the establishment of demonstration zones (23), and optimize the farming space (24) from the perspective of top level design. This study summarizes the stakeholders covered in the above literature, as shown in Table 1. In addition to the policy top level design type of research, the current academic research on deep-sea aquaculture is also mainly focused on aquaculture equipment and technology analysis. Specifically, these can be classified as: research on hydrodynamic characteristics of aquaculture nets and workboats (25, 26); improvement and optimization of aquaculture nets, aquaculture workboats, and aquaculture platforms (2731); selection of aquaculture methods and equipments for different fish species (3234); innovation of automated fish detection technology (35); research on the improvement of net box feed feeding method and automatic feeding technology (36, 37).

      Coverage of stakeholders in existing literature.

      Stakeholder perspective Source of literature
      Government (1619, 21, 23)
      Aquaculture enterprise (20, 22, 24)

      In summary, the existing literature on deep-sea aquaculture has laid a solid theoretical foundation for this study. However, at present, the mechanism for the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture has not yet been established, and the existing researches are mainly in the categories of engineering technology and top level design, which are insufficiently researched as follows: (1) Deep-sea aquaculture not only needs to consider government support and technology development, but also needs to consider the complex game of interests between aquaculture enterprise, service organization and government. However, the research mainly focuses on a single participant and a single factor as the object of research, and lacks of research and consideration of other stakeholders, which has significant limitations. In addition, there are no studies that use evolutionary game model to coordinate the decision-making of various stakeholders and establish a framework for the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture under multi-party coordination. (2) The top level design category of existing studies simply emphasizes the important role of government in the development of deep-sea aquaculture, but ignores the cost burden of government in the process and the potential drawbacks of government intervention. (3) Other factors affecting the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture have not been analyzed in depth.

      Therefore, this study first utilizes an evolutionary game theory model to overcome the limitations of considering a single stakeholder, instead comprehensively analyzing the interactions and strategic evolution among aquaculture enterprise, service organization, and government during the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. Second, while acknowledging the role of government, this study considers the cost issues and government failure issues associated with the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture, aiming to identify the threshold for government intervention and achieve an effective combination of government intervention and market mechanisms, thereby realizing the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. Finally, this study fully considers the importance of initial intention, risk, benefit, and fairness in the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture to enrich the research conclusions.

      Model construction and analysis

      Traditional game theory usually assumes that people are perfectly rational and that participants make decisions under conditions of complete information. However, in real economic life, the conditions of complete rationality and complete information of participants are difficult to achieve. For example, in the competition of enterprises, where there are differences between the participants, the problem of incomplete information and limited rationality due to the economic environment and the complexity of the game problem itself is obvious. Unlike traditional game theory, evolutionary game theory assumes that participants are imperfectly rational and does not require a condition of perfect rationality on the part of the participants. Evolutionary game theory combines game theoretical analysis with dynamic evolutionary process analysis, emphasizing dynamic equilibrium (38).

      Deep-sea aquaculture is different from ordinary fishery farming, the input cost is large, so in reality it is very difficult for fishermen to participate in it, and only aquaculture enterprises with a certain scale and economic strength are able to withstand the risk and bear the cost to participate in deep-sea aquaculture. During the aquaculture process, enterprises involved in deep-sea aquaculture interface with relevant service organizations, while the government plays a guiding, supervisory and supportive role (19). It is worth noting that deep-sea aquaculture service providers are mainly relevant scientific research institutes, as well as private or state-owned enterprises, and that the service providers have a profit-making objective in cooperation with enterprises. Deep-sea aquaculture service organizations also face risk when participating in the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. The main risk factors include the high cost of deep-sea aquaculture technology research and development, which may result in insufficient research funding for service organizations. At the same time, the core objectives of service organizations are knowledge innovation and publication of research results, while the core objectives of aquaculture enterprises are cost reduction and profit increase. There are differences in the cooperation objectives of the two parties, and without government leadership and guidance, the connection between the two parties is weak. In general, in the process of promoting and applying deep-sea aquaculture, enterprises bear the responsibility for deep-sea aquaculture; service organizations make cooperation agreements with enterprises and are responsible for technical support; and the government plays a macro-control role (39). Therefore, based on the evolutionary game theory and referencing existing research (40, 41), this study constructs a three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise—Service organization-Government” under the joint action of market mechanism and government guidance. The relevant model is shown in Figure 1.

      Evolutionary game model diagram.

      Diagram showing relationships between government, aquaculture enterprise, and service organization. Government regulates both the aquaculture enterprise and service organization. The aquaculture enterprise and service organization are in a collaborative relationship.
      Evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise—service organization”

      Before constructing the three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise-Service organization-Governmen,” in order to verify the importance of government involvement, this study firstly constructs a two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise-Service organization” to investigate the strategy evolution of the two players in the absence of government involvement.

      Assumptions of the two-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise—service organization”

      H1: Under the condition of market mechanism, the evolutionary game model for the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture should be a two-party evolutionary game model, which is the aquaculture enterprise (Q) and the related service organization (W). The relationship between them is cooperative, with aquaculture enterprise requesting and paying for services related to deep-sea aquaculture from the relevant service organization. In accordance with the principle of maximizing the benefits of each participant, in the model, aquaculture enterprise will choose whether to implement deep-sea aquaculture or not, and relevant service organization will choose whether to provide deep-sea aquaculture service support for aquaculture enterprise or not.

      H2: Based on Hypothesis 1, the strategy combinations of aquaculture enterprise is whether to engage in deep-sea aquaculture or not, respectively, the strategy space is α = (α1, α2), and this study hypothesizes that the willingness of aquaculture enterprise to participate in deep-sea aquaculture (α1) is X, while the willingness not to participate in deep-sea aquaculture (α2) is 1-X, and X ∈ [0.1]. The strategy combination of the service organization is whether to provide deep-sea aquaculture services or not, and the strategy space is β = (β1, β2). In this study, it is assumed that the willingness of the service organization to provide deep-sea aquaculture services (β1) is Y and the willingness not to provide deep-sea aquaculture services (β2) is 1-Y, Y ∈ [0.1].

      H3: Deep-sea aquaculture enterprise usually have a certain foundation in the aquaculture industry, and service organization also provides services related to offshore aquaculture before providing deep-sea aquaculture services. Therefore, this study assumes that aquaculture enterprise and service organization are not choosing between offshore aquaculture and deep-sea aquaculture, but choosing whether to select deep-sea aquaculture or not on the basis of offshore aquaculture. Based on the cost–benefit function, this study assumes that the cost of implementing offshore aquaculture in aquaculture enterprises is C1 and the benefit of implementing offshore aquaculture is R1; the cost of providing services for offshore aquaculture in service organization is C2 and the benefit of providing services for offshore aquaculture is R2. It is important to note that R1 > C1, R2 > C2. After participating in deep-sea aquaculture, the additional cost of deep-sea aquaculture to be paid by the aquaculture enterprise is C3, the additional cost to be paid by the service organization is C4, the benefit from the implementation of deep-sea aquaculture by the aquaculture enterprise is R3, and the benefit from the service organization’s provision of deep-sea aquaculture services is R4. It is important to note that R3 > C3, R4 > C4. In addition, engaging in deep-sea aquaculture involves a high degree of uncertainty and risk, because of the extreme sea weather that deep-sea aquaculture faces. Therefore, this study assumes that the risk cost of implementing deep-sea aquaculture is C, and that a single individual is likely to be unable to bear the entire risk cost independently. The corresponding parameter relationship can be expressed as: R3-C3-C < 0; R4-C4-C < 0。Because of the cooperative relationship between aquaculture enterprise and service organization, both of them share the risk in the actual process of cooperation. This study assumes that the cost of deep-sea aquaculture risk undertaken by aquaculture enterprise is C7 and the cost of deep-sea aquaculture risk undertaken by service organization is C8, C=C7 + C8. When they cooperate, they can share the cost of risk, in which case R3-C3-C7 > 0; R4-C4-C8 > 0. At the same time, deep-sea aquaculture has the characteristics of high risk and high return, so the average return of the implementation of deep-sea aquaculture should be greater than the average return of offshore aquaculture, in order to facilitate the calculation, this study set the total return of deep-sea aquaculture is higher than the total return of offshore aquaculture, and the specific relationship can be expressed as follows: R3-C3-C7 > R1-C1; R4-C4-C8 > R2-C2. In addition, the risk cost coefficient is T, C7 = T * C, C8 = (1 − T) * C, and T ∈ [0.1].

      H4: Collaboration between aquaculture enterprise and service organization not only satisfy their respective needs, but also generate benefit from the collaboration. These benefits include resource sharing, cost saving and risk sharing. Therefore, this study assumes that the cooperation benefit from the implementation of deep-sea aquaculture by the aquaculture enterprise and the service organization is R. If one of the parties does not participate in deep-sea aquaculture, there is no cooperation benefit. The coefficient of distribution of the cooperation benefit is A. The cooperation benefit obtained by the aquaculture enterprise is R*A, and the cooperation benefit obtained by the service organization is R*(1-A), A ∈ [0.1].

      The detailed parameter list is shown in Table 2.

      Parameters of the two-party evolutionary game model.

      Parameter Parameter name Exegesis
      X Willingness to participate in deep-sea aquaculture 0 ≤ X ≤ 1
      Y Willingness to provide deep-sea aquaculture services 0 ≤ Y ≤ 1
      C1 Cost of offshore aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise C1 < R1; C1 < C3
      C2 Cost of offshore aquaculture service in service organization C2 < R2; C2 < C4
      C3 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise C3 < R3; C1 < C3
      C4 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture service in service organization C4 < R4; C2 < C4
      C7 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture risk in aquaculture enterprise C=C7 + C8
      C8 Cost of risk in deep-sea aquaculture in service organization C=C7 + C8
      C Total cost of risk C=C7 + C8
      T Risk cost coefficient 0 ≤ T ≤ 1
      R1 Benefit of offshore aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise R1 < R3; C1 < R1
      R2 Benefit of offshore aquaculture service in service organization R2 < R4; C2 < R2
      R3 Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise R1 < R3; C3 < R3
      R4 Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture service in service organization R2 < R4; C4 < R4
      R Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture cooperation
      A Cooperation benefit coefficient 0 ≤ A ≤ 1
      Analysis of the two-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprises—service organizations.”

      (1) Expected return function and replication of dynamic equation of aquaculture enterprise.

      Based on the payment matrix in Table 3, the expected return function for each decision combination of the aquaculture enterprise can be solved, assuming that the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vx11, and that the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise not participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vx21, and that the average expected return is Vx. Specifically, see Equation (1).

      {Vx11=(AR+R1+R3C1C3C7)y+(R1+R3C1C3C)(1y)Vx21=(R1C1)y+(R1C1)(1y)V¯x=xVx11+(1x)Vx21

      Payment matrix of the two-party evolutionary game model.

      Aquaculture enterprise
      Participation Non-participation
      Service organization Participation A*R + R1 + R3-C1-C3-C7(1-A)*R + R2 + R4-C2-C4-C8 R1-C1R2 + R4-C2-C4-C
      Non-participation R1 + R3-C1-C3-CR2-C2 R1-C1R2-C2

      Based on the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise, the dynamic equation of replication of the aquaculture enterprise can be derived, as shown in Equation (2).

      F(x)=dxdt=x(x1)(C+C3R3Cy+C7yARy)

      (2) Expected return function and replication dynamic equation for service organization.

      It is assumed that the expected return function for service organizations involved in deep-sea aquaculture is Vy11, the expected return function for not participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vy21, and the average expected return is Vy. Specifically, see Equation (3).

      {Vy11=[(1A)R+R2+R4C2C4C8]x+(R2+R4C2C4C)(1x)Vy21=(R2C2)x+(R2C2)(1x)V¯y=yVy11+(1y)Vy21

      Based on the expected return function of the service organization, the replication dynamic equation of the service organization can be derived, as shown in Equation (4).

      F(y)=dydt=y(y1)(C+C4R4Cx+C8xRx+ARx)
      Stability point analysis of the two-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise- service organization”

      According to Equation (2) and Equation (4), the Jacobi matrix of the two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization” can be constructed. So that F (x) = 0; F (y) = 0, can find the equilibrium point of the two-party evolutionary game model. The Jacobi matrix of the two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization” is shown in Equation (5).

      J1=[0,x(x1)(CC7+AR)y(y1)(CC8+RAR),0]

      Based on existing research, according to Lyapunov’s first method (42), equilibria are asymptotically stable if all eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix have a negative real part, while these equilibria can be called stable points (ESS) only if they satisfy strict Nash equilibrium and pure strategy equilibrium. The equilibrium point is unstable if at least one of the eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix has a positive real part. The stability of the equilibrium point cannot be determined if the Jacobi matrix has negative real parts except for the eigenvalues that have a real part of zero. Four equilibrium points of the two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization” were calculated: E1 (0,0), E2 (1,0), E3 (0,1), and E4 (1,1). At this time the four equilibrium points constitute the boundary of the evolutionary game domain, the equilibrium points within the boundary are mixed strategy Nash equilibrium, but none of them are stable equilibrium points, so this study focuses on the asymptotic stability of the four boundary equilibrium points mentioned above in the two-party evolutionary game. After substituting each of the above four equilibria into the Jacobi matrix, the eigenvalues are derived, as shown in Table 4.

      Eigenvalues of Jacobi matrix.

      ESS λ1 λ2
      E1(0,0) R3 - C3 - C R4 - C4 - C
      E2(1,0) C + C3 - R3 R - C8 - C4 + R4 - A*R
      E3(0,1) C + C4 - R4 R3 - C7 - C3 + A*R
      E4(1,1) C3 + C7 - R3 - A*R C4 + C8 - R4 -(1-A)*R

      Based on the assumptions of this study, it can be seen that there are two stable points in the two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise-Service organization,” which are E1 (0, 0) and E4 (1, 1). It can be seen that, without government participation and relying only on the market mechanism, the model is unable to reach the equilibrium point E4 in a stable manner, which is due to the fact that the cost of deep-sea aquaculture is too high, and the aquaculture enterprise and service organization are unwilling to take the risk, and then relying only on the market mechanism will lead to the phenomenon of market failure. Therefore, in order to study the importance of government participation, this study continues to construct a three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization-Government” to investigate the stability of the model.

      A three-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise- service organization-government” Assumptions of the three-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise- service organization-government”

      H5: Because of the high cost of inputs required for deep-sea aquaculture, it is difficult to rely only on enterprise and service organization, and in order to reduce the risk of each participant and increase the willingness to participate, the government (E) needs to play a macro-control role and provide support for aquaculture enterprise and related service organization. Therefore, the government’s strategic combination is whether to provide deep-sea aquaculture support or not. In summary, this study constructed a three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization-Government” on the basis of the two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise-Service organization.” The government’s strategy portfolio is whether to provide deep-sea aquaculture support or not, and the strategy space is θ = (θ1, θ2). In this study, it is assumed that the government’s willingness to provide deep-sea aquaculture support (θ1) is Z, and its willingness not to provide deep-sea aquaculture support (θ2) is 1-Z, Z ∈ [0.1].

      H6: In order to increase the motivation of aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate in deep-sea aquaculture, the government will give subsidies to aquaculture enterprise and service organization at the beginning. Assume that the government grants deep-sea aquaculture subsidies to the aquaculture enterprise is S1, and grants deep-sea aquaculture subsidies to the service organization is S2, the total subsidy is S, and the subsidy coefficient is T. The specific relationship can be expressed as follows: S1 = S*T, S2 = S*(1-T), and T∈[0.1]. In addition, the government likewise plays a supervisory role by imposing penalties if a party is found to be in breach of contract, i.e., when one party adopts a positive cooperation strategy while the other adopts a negative cooperation strategy, the penalty is K1 for the enterprise and K2 for the service organization.

      Scenario 7: Both general and deep-sea aquaculture place a burden on the environment. While environmental regulations, such as discharge permits, internalize private costs so that enterprises bear the costs of environmental damage, the government also bears the environmental costs of environmental damage caused by economic development. It is important to note that this study incorporates the privately borne compensation for environmental damage into the cost of business. In summary, this study assumes that the government will bear the environmental cost of offshore aquaculture as C5, and the environmental cost of deep-sea aquaculture as C6. In addition, deep-sea aquaculture will to a certain extent play a role in ecological restoration, and therefore it is assumed that the environmental benefits of deep-sea aquaculture will be R5, which belongs to the positive externality benefits that cannot be appropriated by the aquaculture enterprise, and the government ultimately appropriates them. Meanwhile, in the process of providing deep-sea aquaculture service, service organization will generate relevant patents or intellectual property rights (such as research and development of seedling and development of new types of equipment), and although these benefits are incorporated into the service organization, they will potentially generate benefits related to the national strategic level and improve the country’s international status, so this study assumes that the strategic benefits brought by the provision of deep-sea aquaculture service is R6.

      The detailed parameter list and payment matrix are shown in Tables 5, 6.

      Parameters of the three-party evolutionary game model.

      Parameter Parameter name Exegesis
      X Willingness to participate in deep-sea aquaculture 0 ≤ X ≤ 1
      Y Willingness to provide deep-sea aquaculture services 0 ≤ Y ≤ 1
      Z Willingness to support deep-sea aquaculture 0 ≤ Z ≤ 1
      C1 Cost of offshore aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise C1 < R1; C1 < C3
      C2 Cost of offshore aquaculture service in service organization C2 < R2; C2 < C4
      C3 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise C3 < R3; C1 < C3
      C4 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture service in service organization C4 < R4; C2 < C4
      C5 Environmental cost of offshore aquaculture C5 > C6
      C6 Environmental cost of deep-sea aquaculture C5 > C6; C6 < R5
      C7 Cost of deep-sea aquaculture risk in aquaculture enterprise C=C7 + C8
      C8 Cost of risk in deep-sea aquaculture in service organization C=C7 + C8
      C Total cost of risk C=C7 + C8
      T Risk cost coefficient 0 ≤ T ≤ 1
      R1 Benefit of offshore aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise R1 < R3; C1 < R1
      R2 Benefit of offshore aquaculture service in service organization R2 < R4; C2 < R2
      R3 Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise R1 < R3; C3 < R3
      R4 Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture service in service organization R2 < R4; C4 < R4
      R5 Environmental benefit of deep-sea aquaculture C6 < R5
      R6 Strategic benefit of deep-sea aquaculture
      R Benefit of deep-sea aquaculture cooperation
      A Cooperation benefit coefficient 0 ≤ A ≤ 1
      S1 Subsidies for deep-sea aquaculture in aquaculture enterprise S=S1 + S2
      S2 Subsidies for deep-sea aquaculture in service organization S=S1 + S2
      K1 Penalties for aquaculture enterprise
      K2 Penalties for service organization
      S Deep-sea aquaculture total subsidies S=S1 + S2
      B Subsidy coefficient 0 ≤ B ≤ 1

      Payment matrix for the three-party evolutionary game model.

      Government
      Support: Z Not support:1-Z
      Aquaculture enterprise involved in deep-sea aquaculture: X Service organization involved in deep-sea aquaculture: Y A*R + R1 + R3-C1-C3 + B*S-C7(1-A)*R + R2 + R4-C2-C4 + (1-B)*S-C8R5 + R6-C5-C6-S A*R + R1 + R3-C1-C3-C7A*R + R2 + R4-C2-C4-C8R5 + R6-C5-C6
      Service organization not involved in deep-sea aquaculture:1-Y R1 + R3-C1-C3-C + S1 R1 + R3-C1-C3-C
      R2-C2-K2 R2-C2
      R5-C5-C6-S1-S3 R5-C5-C6
      Aquaculture enterprise not involved in deep-sea aquaculture:1-X Service organization involved in deep-sea aquaculture: Y R1-C1-K1 R1-C1
      R2 + R4-C2-C4-C + S2 R2 + R4-C2-C4-C
      R6-C5-S2 + K1 R6-C5
      Service organization not involved in deep-sea aquaculture:1-Y R1-C1-K1 R1-C1
      R2-C2-K2 R2-C2
      -C5 + K1 + K2 -C5
      Analysis of the three-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise- service organization-government.”

      (1) Expected return function and replication dynamic equation of aquaculture enterprise.

      Based on the payment matrix in Table 6, the expected return function for each decision combination of the aquaculture enterprise can be solved, assuming that the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vx11, and that the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise not participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vx21, with an average expected return of Vx. Specifically, it is shown in Equation (6).

      {Vχ11=(AR+R1+R3C1C3+BSC7)yz+(AR+R1+R3C1C3C7)y(1z)+(R1+R3C1C3C+S1+S3)(1y)z+(R1+R3C1C3C)(1Y)(1z)Vχ21=(R1C1)yz+(R1C1)y(1z)+(R1C1)(1y)z+(R1C1)(1y)(1z)V¯χ=χVχ11+(1χ)Vχ21

      Based on the expected return function of the aquaculture enterprise, the replication dynamic equation of the aquaculture enterprise can be obtained as, as shown in Equation (7).

      F(x)=dxdt=x(x1)(R3C3C+CyC7y+K1z+S1z+ARyS1yz+SByz)

      (2) Expected return function and replication dynamic equation of service organizations.

      It is assumed that the expected return function of service organization participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vy11, the expected return function of not participating in deep-sea aquaculture is Vy21, and the average expected return is Vy. Specifically, it is shown in Equation (8).

      {Vy11=[(1A)R+R2+R4C2C4+(1B)SC8)xz+[(1A)R+R2+R4C2C4C8)Ax(1z)+(R2+R4C2C4C+S2)(1x)z+(R2+R4C2C4C)(1x)(1z)Vy21=(R2C2K2)xz+(R2C2)x(1z)+(R2C2K2)(1x)z+(R2C2)(1x)(1z)V¯y=yVy11+(1y)Vy21

      Based on the expected return function of the service organization, the dynamic equation of replication of the service organization can be derived, as shown in Equation (9).

      F(y)=dydt=y(y1)(C+C4R4Cx+C8xK2zRxS2z+ARxSxz+S2xz+SBxz)

      (3) Expected return function and replication dynamic equation for the government.

      Assuming that the expected return function for government support for deep-sea aquaculture is Vz11, the expected return function for no support for deep-sea aquaculture is Vz21, and the average expected return is Vz. Specifically it is shown in Equation (10).

      {VZ11=(R5+R6C5C6S)xy+R5C5C6S1+K2)Ax(1y)+(R6C5S2+K1)(1x)y+(C5+K1+K2)(1x)(1y)VZ21=(R5+R6C5C6)xy+(R5C5C6)x(1y)+(R6C5)(1x)yC5(1x)(1y)V¯Z=zVZ11+(1z)VZ21

      Based on the government’s expected return function, the government’s dynamic equation for replication can be derived, as shown in Equation (11).

      F(z)=dzdt=z(z1)(K1xK2K1+K2y+S1x+S2y+SxyS1xyS2xy)
      Analysis of the stability point of the three-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise- service organization- government”

      According to Equation (7), Equation (9), Equation (11), this study can construct the Jacobi matrix of the three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization-Government,” make F (x) = 0; F (y) = 0, F (z) = 0 can be obtained the equilibrium point of the three-party evolutionary game model. Due to the three-party evolutionary game Jacobi matrix is too long, so the study uses symbols instead, Jacobi matrix as shown in Equation (12).

      [diff(fx,x)diff(fx,y)diff(fx,z)diff(fy,x)diff(fy,y)diff(fy,z)diff(fz,x)diff(fz,y)diff(fz,z)]

      The three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization-Government” has eight pure strategy equilibrium points: E1(0,0,0), E2(1,0,0), E3(0,1,0), E4(0,0,1), E5(1,1,0), E6(1,0,1), E7(0,1,1), E8(1,1,1). Substituting the equilibrium points into the Jacobi matrix, respectively, leads to the eigenvalues as shown in Table 7. According to the assumptions of this study, the sign of the eigenvalues of the equilibrium points of the Jacobi matrix is shown in Table 8.

      Eigenvalues of the Jacobi matrix for the three-party evolutionary game model.

      ESS λ1 λ2 λ3
      E1(0,0,0) R3 - C3 - C R4 - C4 - C K1 + K2
      E2(1,0,0) C + C3 - R3 R - C8 - C4 + R4 - A*R K2 - S1
      E3(0,1,0) R3 - C7 - C3 + A*R C + C4 - R4 K1 - S2
      E4(0,0,1) K1 - C3 - C + R3 + S1 K2 - C4 - C + R4 + S2 - K1 - K2
      E5(1,1,0) C3 + C7 - R3 - A*R C4 + C8 - R - R4 + A*R -S
      E6(1,0,1) C + C3 - K1 - R3 - S1 K2 - C8 - C4 + R + R4 + S - S*B - A*R S1 - K2
      E7(0,1,1) K1 - C7 - C3 + R3 + S*B + A*R C + C4 - K2 - R4 - S2 S2 - K1
      E8(1,1,1) C3 + C7 - K1 - R3 - S*B - A*R C4 + C8 - K2 - R - R4 - S + S*B + A*R S

      Signs of the eigenvalues of the equilibrium points of the three party evolutionary game model.

      Equilibrium point Eigenvalues translation
      λ1 λ2 λ3 Stability
      E1(0,0,0) + NESS
      E2(1,0,0) + + × NESS
      E3(0,1,0) + + × NESS
      E4(0,0,1) × × NESS
      E5(1,1,0) ESS
      E6(1,0,1) + × NESS
      E7(0,1,1) + × × NESS
      E8(1,1,1) × × + NESS

      × stands for sign uncertainty, ESS stands for stable point and NESS stands for non-stable point.

      According to Table 8, it can be seen that based on the assumptions of this study, compared with the two-party evolutionary game model, the equilibrium point of the three-party evolutionary game model is E5 (1, 1, 0), and is not affected by the value of the parameter, and it is always a stable point. E1 (0, 0, 0) cannot be a stable point, which indicates that the government’s intervention and support effectively guarantees the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture.

      In addition, the following clarifications are needed in this study:

      (1) According to the eigenvalues of Jacobi matrix, it can be seen that in order to avoid the failure of government intervention, which leads to E4(0,0,1) becoming the equilibrium point, the government’s participation in the process of promoting the application of deep-sea aquaculture has three measure options. First, good subsidy measures, the subsidy should be greater than or equal to the risk cost borne by a single individual independently engaging in deep-sea aquaculture, the specific relationship can be expressed as: S1 ≥ R3-C3-C or S2 ≥ R4-C4-C. Second, strengthen the supervision, and strengthen the punishment of violators of cooperation or those who are negatively treated, and the amount of punishment should be greater than or equal to the risk cost borne by a single individual independently engaging in deep-sea aquaculture, and the specific relationship can be expressed as K1 ≥ R3-C3-C or K2 ≥ R4-C4-C. Third, the government can also act on subsidies and penalties at the same time, so that the sum of the penalty amount and the subsidy amount is greater than or equal to the risk cost borne by a single individual independently engaging in deep-sea aquaculture.

      (2) The three-party evolutionary game model can never be stabilized at E8 (1, 1, 1), which indicates that the government cannot continuously intervene in the process of deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application. The main reasons are: firstly, the special characteristics of deep-sea aquaculture lead to high input costs, high technological uncertainty, and large subsidies required, and sustained subsidies will exacerbate the government’s financial burdens and increase the government’s fiscal deficits. Secondly, in the short term, government intervention, especially policy subsidies, will reduce the initial investment risk of deep-sea aquaculture and stimulate the rapid expansion of the deep-sea aquaculture industry. However, in the long term, as the scale of the industry expands, the marginal benefit of government subsidies will decrease, but the government’s financial burden will continue to rise, and even the enterprise will rely on government subsidies to maintain its operation rather than to improve the efficiency of its operation, thus creating the phenomenon of “policy parasitism.” Finally, the continued imposition of penalties by the government, although it will force aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate in deep-sea aquaculture, is not in line with the rule of the market, and will ultimately lead to a failure of the market and government intervention at the same time. In addition, three-party evolutionary game model can stabilize at E5 (1, 1, 0) indicating that as the deep-sea aquaculture industry continues to develop, aquaculture enterprises and service institutions no longer rely on government subsidies but instead rely on market mechanisms to operate independently, and the need for government intervention is gradually decreasing.

      Simulation analysis Parameter assignment

      In order to more intuitively study the strategy evolution of each participant and more deeply explore the influencing factors in the process of deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application, this study continues to simulate and analysis the evolutionary game model. Based on the previous assumptions, this study assigns values to each parameter, and the detailed parameter assignment table is shown in Table 9.

      Parameter assigned values for the evolutionary game model.

      Parameter C1 C2 C3 C4 C5 C6 C7 C8 C T
      15 5 20 20 15 10 25 25 50 0.5
      R1 R2 R3 R4 R5 R6 R A S1 S2
      20 10 60 60 30 40 30 0.5 10 10
      K1 K2 S B x y z
      5 5 20 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5
      Evolutionary combinatorial diagram analysis

      According to the parameters set in this study, this study plots the evolutionary game combinations based on the two-party evolutionary game model and the three-party evolutionary game model established above. See the detail in Figures 2, 3.

      Combination diagram of two-party evolutionary game.

      Logarithmic spiral plot featuring multiple colored lines converging towards the top right corner. The horizontal axis is labeled “x” ranging from zero to one, and the vertical axis is labeled “y” ranging from zero to one, both with gridlines for reference.

      Combination diagram of three-party evolutionary game.

      Three-dimensional plot showing a series of colorful, curving lines representing data trajectories. Axes labeled x, y, and z range from 0 to 1. Lines have varied colors, creating a flowing, dynamic visual.

      According to Figure 2, it can be seen that in the absence of government intervention, there is a tendency of “participation, participation” and “non-participation, non-participation” between enterprise and service organization. Meanwhile, according to Table 3, it can be inferred that as the total cost of risk rises, the participating entities will tend to be more and more inclined to “non-participation, non-participation.” The results of the analysis in Figure 2 are corroborated by the results of the analysis in Table 3. According to Figure 3, it can be seen that the three-party evolutionary game model converges to the stable point E5(1,1,0) after the government intervention is adopted, indicating that the government intervention can effectively improve the willingness to participate in deep-sea aquaculture of aquaculture enterprise and service organization. Meanwhile, according to Figure 3, it can also be seen that in the evolution process, no matter how high the government’s willingness to participate is, it finally converges to the stable point E5, which is corroborated with the results of the analysis in Table 7.

      Numerical simulation analysis Analysis of the impact of initial willingness to participate

      In order to study the impact of the initial willingness of each participant on the process and outcome of the evolutionary game, this study assigns the initial willingness of aquaculture enterprise, service organization, and government to 0.2, 0.5, and 0.7, with the corresponding colors of red, blue, and green, respectively, while the rest of the parameters remain unchanged, and plots Figure 4. In Figure 4, from left to right, the impact of the change in the initial willingness of each of the aquaculture enterprise, service organization and government on the process and outcome of the evolutionary game is shown respectively, with the x-axis being the evolutionary cycle and the y-axis being the initial willingness to participate.

      Analysis of the impact of initial willingness.

      Three line graphs display proportions over time with varying parameters, labeled x, y, and z. Each graph has lines representing values 0.2, 0.5, and 0.7. The left and center graphs show increasing proportions, peaking at 1. The right graph shows a decreasing pattern.

      Figure 4 shows that the stronger the initial willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization, the faster they will choose to participate in deep-sea aquaculture. The government, as the initial willingness increases, will tend to 0 at a slower rate, and when the initial willingness of all parties to participate is 0.2, the government’s willingness to participate shows a tendency to rise first and then decrease. The analysis of the impact of initial willingness to participate explains the mechanism of the stage-by-stage evolution of deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application. In the early stage of industrial development, facing the dilemma of negative willingness to participate of both aquaculture enterprise and service organization, the government needs to stimulate the market vitality effectively through institutional intervention. Specifically, through the implementation of intervention strategies, such as financial subsidies and tax incentives to resolve the cost concerns of market entities, and targeted industrial policy push to solve the information asymmetry problem. Along with the initial formation of the cooperation network between aquaculture enterprise and service organization and the gradual improvement of the market mechanism, the intensity of government intervention will be adjusted according to the degree of improvement of the market mechanism, and the role of the government will be changed from a dominant character to a service-oriented character, so as to ultimately realize the smooth transition of the deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application from an administrative-driven approach to a market-driven approach.

      Analysis of the impact of deep-sea aquaculture risk

      In order to study the impact of risk cost on the process and outcome of the evolutionary game of each participating subject, this study assigns the total risk cost as 20, 50 and 80, with the corresponding colors of red, blue and green, while keeping the rest of the parameters unchanged, and plots Figure 5. In Figure 5, the evolutionary game process and result of the aquaculture enterprise and service organization and the government are shown from left to right, with the x-axis being the evolutionary cycle and the y-axis being the willingness of the participating entities to participate. In order to explore the risk cost coefficient on the evolutionary game process and result of each participating subject, this study assigns the risk cost coefficient as 0.3, 0.5, and 0.7, with corresponding colors of red, blue and green, while keeping the rest of the parameters unchanged, and plots Figure 6. In Figure 6, the evolutionary game process and result of the aquaculture enterprise and service organization and the government are shown from left to right, with the x-axis being the evolutionary cycle and the y-axis being the willingness of the participating entities to participate.

      Analysis of the impact of the cost of risk.

      Three line graphs show the proportion over time for different values of C: twenty, fifty, and eighty, represented by red, blue, and green lines respectively. The first two graphs depict increasing trends, while the third shows a decreasing trend, with the green line being notably distinct from the others in shape.

      Analysis of the impact of the cost of risk coefficient.

      Three graphs show proportions over time for different T values: 0.3, 0.5, and 0.7. The left and middle graphs depict a steep rise, converging around 0.6, while the right graph shows a decline, resembling the patterns in the first two graphs.

      According to Figure 5, it can be seen that as the cost of risk rises, the willingness to participate of each participant changes. When the total risk cost rises from 20 to 50, the speed of convergence of the willingness to participate of the enterprise, service organization and government decreases. When the risk cost becomes 80, the excessive risk cost makes the probability of participants engaging in deep-sea aquaculture suffering from losses too large, aquaculture enterprise and service organization cannot form the motivation to participate, and at this time, the government cannot effectively mobilize the enthusiasm of the both of them through intervention. Therefore, the model evolution result shows that the willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate converges to 0, and the willingness of the government to participate converges to 1. The government intervention does not achieve the desired effect, and government failure occurs at this time. According to Figure 6, it can be seen that as the cost of risk taking by aquaculture enterprise rises, the willingness of enterprise to participate tends to 1 slower, while the willingness of service organization to participate tends to 1 faster, and the degree of fit between them decreases. At the same time, there is no impact on the government’s willingness to participate, because the total cost has not changed. The analysis of risk cost of deep-sea aquaculture reveals the key rule of risk transmission in the process of deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application: when the risk cost breaks through the threshold, aquaculture enterprise and service organizations will produce negative psychology due to the “loss aversion effect,” and then the government’s unidirectional intervention triggers the trap of adverse selection, resulting in the failure of the government. When the proportion of risk structure is imbalanced, aquaculture enterprise bears too much risk, the risk transfer mechanism prompts service organization to participate in the enthusiasm, but there is also the phenomenon that aquaculture enterprise and service organization cannot be matched effectively, resulting in the loss of cooperation efficiency.

      Analysis of the impact of benefits from deep-sea aquaculture cooperation

      In order to study the influence of cooperation benefits on the process and result of the evolutionary game of each participating subject, this study assigns the values of 30, 50, 60 to the total cooperation benefits and 0.5, 0.6, 0.9 to the coefficient of distribution of the cooperation benefits, while keeping the rest of the parameters unchanged, with the corresponding colors of red, blue and green, respectively, and plots Figure 7. In Figure 7, the impacts of the evolutionary gaming process and result of aquaculture enterprise, service organization and government are shown from left to right, with the x-axis showing the evolutionary cycle and the y-axis showing the willingness to participate of the participating entities.

      Analysis of the impact of cooperation benefits and distribution coefficient.

      Three line graphs show the proportion over time for different conditions. The first graph has R equals thirty, A equals zero point three, fifty, and sixty, with A equals zero point nine. The second graph has R equals thirty, A equals zero point five, fifty, and sixty, with A equals zero point nine. The third graph has R equals thirty, A equals zero point five, fifty, and sixty, with A equals zero point nine. Each graph shows a trend with lines in red, blue, and green tracking similar patterns.

      According to Figure 7, it can be seen that the willingness of enterprise to participate tends to 1 at a faster rate as the benefits of cooperation and the coefficient of distribution of the benefits of cooperation among aquaculture enterprise increase. On the contrary, when the cooperation benefits are 30 and the allocation coefficient of the service organization is 0.5, the service organization can get cooperation benefits of 15, and when the cooperation benefits are 50 and the allocation coefficient of the service organization is 0.4, the service organization can get cooperation benefits of 20, so the willingness of the service organization to participate tends to 1 faster. When the cooperation benefits continue to rise to become 60 and the service organization allocation coefficient falls to 0.1, the cooperation benefits available to the service organization at this point are 6, so the willingness to participate tends to 1 at a much lower rate. The government, on the other hand, tends toward a slightly faster willingness to participate of 0 as total cooperation benefits rise, this is because as the benefits of enterprise and service organization rise, motivation increases and the government is able to end its intervention earlier. However, if the distribution of the benefits of cooperation is never equitable, there will also be a mismatch between the willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate, and the efficiency of cooperation will be impaired. The analysis of the impacts of cooperation benefits and distribution coefficient reveals the dual driving mechanism of cooperation benefit distribution in the process of deep-sea aquaculture promotion and application. Firstly, the efficiency mechanism: the strategy selection of the participating subjects follows the principle of profit maximization, and the willingness to participate shows a significant positive correlation with the absolute benefits. Secondly, the equity mechanism: when the total cooperation benefit is in conflict with its own allocation coefficient, there is an imbalance in equity, and the reverse driving mechanism is triggered after reaching a critical value, resulting in an impairment of the efficiency of cooperation between the two parties. This essentially reflects the “efficiency-equity” interaction in cooperation, and the driving mechanism needs to satisfy the dual conditions of expansion of the scale of benefits and a reasonable structure of benefit distribution.

      Analysis of the combined impact of cost and government intervention

      In order to investigate the evolution process and result of the strategies of each participant under the combined influence of cost and government intervention. In this study, the cost of deep-sea aquaculture for aquaculture enterprise was assigned as 20, 30, and 40, and the cost of deep-sea aquaculture for service organization was assigned as 20, 25, and 30, respectively, while the rest of the parameters were kept unchanged. The total government subsidy is set to 20, 40 and 60 and the penalties are set to 5, 10, and 15. The corresponding colors are red, blue and green and are plotted in Figure 8. In Figure 8, the impacts of the evolutionary gaming process and result of aquaculture enterprise, service organization and government are shown from left to right, with the x-axis showing the evolutionary cycle and the y-axis showing the willingness to participate of the participating entities.

      Analysis of the combined impact of cost and government intervention.

      Three line graphs show the proportion against time for different parameter settings. Each graph has a legend with configurations: C3, C4, S, K1, and K2, with values such as C3=20, C4=20, S=20, K1=K2=5. The graphs depict rising and falling trends based on these parameters.

      According to Figure 8, it can be seen that even though the intensity of government intervention and the cost of deep-sea aquaculture rise together, the rate of convergence of aquaculture enterprise and service organization still slows down as the cost rises. And when the cost reaches 60, the speed of convergence decreases substantially. This is because at this point the benefits of participating in deep-sea aquaculture are already negative, and the reason why aquaculture enterprise and service organization continue to converge at 1 is attributed to government intervention. Governments, on the other hand, converge progressively faster as the cost of intervention rises. In summary, this simultaneous rise in cost and subsidy leads to an eventual dilemma where the government bears high costs while failing to increase the willingness of participating entities to participate. The analysis of the combined impact of cost and government intervention shows that every policy tool must comply with the rule of the market, and government intervention that violates the rule of the market will not only lead to the dilemma of double failure of the government and the market, but will also lead to the transformation of aquaculture enterprise and service organization from value creation to subsidy dependence, and the basis of decision-making from profit-driven to policy arbitrage-driven. Analysis of the combined impact of cost and government intervention indicates that any policy tool must conform to market principles. Government intervention that violates market principles not only leads to a situation of double failure of government and market, but also causes aquaculture enterprise and service organization to shift from value creation to subsidy dependence. At this point, the double failure of government and market is mainly manifested in the inability of aquaculture enterprises and service organizations to cooperate through market mechanisms, and the government paying high intervention costs without achieving the expected results.

      Conclusion

      The study analyzed the influencing factors in the promotion and application of deep sea aquaculture by constructing a two-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise -Service organization” and a three-party evolutionary game model of “Aquaculture enterprise- Service organization-Government.” The main conclusions are as follow:

      (1) By constructing a two-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise-service organization” and conducting stability analysis, it is found that the two-party evolutionary game model has two equilibrium points: (0, 0) and (1, 1), and neither participant can stably choose an active participation strategy. After introducing government intervention, the three-party evolutionary game model shows that the three-party evolutionary game model of “aquaculture enterprise–service organization–government” stably converges to (1, 1, 0).

      (2) Analysis of the impact of initial willingness to participate shows that the initial willingness of each participating entity to participate significantly affects the strategic choices of aquaculture enterprise and service organization. The stronger the initial willingness, the greater the likelihood that participating entities will actively engage in deep-sea aquaculture. However, when the willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate is too low, the willingness of the government to participate shows a trend of first increasing and then decreasing.

      (3) Simulation analysis of risk cost and risk coefficient shows that if the risk cost of deep-sea aquaculture is too high, it will cause the willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization to participate to tend toward 0. This threshold is when the sum of risk and cost exceeds the sum of potential profits from deep-sea aquaculture and government subsidies received. At this point, the government’s willingness to participate tends toward 1, but it is still unable to effectively promote the effective participation of aquaculture enterprise and service organization in deep-sea aquaculture.

      (4) Simulation analysis of cooperation benefit and distribution coefficient shows that an increase in cooperation benefit between aquaculture enterprise and service organization will enhance the willingness of both parties to participate in deep-sea aquaculture through efficiency mechanisms, enabling the government to end intervention more quickly. However, when cooperation benefit distribution is imbalanced, it will lead to a mismatch in the willingness of aquaculture enterprise or service organization to participate.

      (5) Simulation analysis under the combined impact of cost and government intervention shows that as the cost of participating in deep-sea aquaculture and government subsidy both rise, and the subsidy increases at a faster rate, the convergence speed of enterprise and service organization still slows down, and government intervention fails to achieve the expected results.

      Discussion

      The above research conclusion reveals the core mechanisms and main contradictions in the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. Based on the research conclusion, the following insights can be drawn:

      (1) The stability results of the three-party evolutionary game model indicate that relying solely on market mechanisms is insufficient to effectively promote the widespread adoption of deep-sea aquaculture. Government intervention is crucial for the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. However, due to the high cost of deep-sea aquaculture, government intervention is also expensive, and the diminishing marginal effect of subsidy leads to the government eventually withdrawing from the game. Therefore, the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture should transition from initial strong government intervention to gradually weakening government intervention. Once the deep-sea aquaculture market and industry are preliminarily established, the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture should be fully driven by marketmechanism.

      (2) Analysis of initial participation willingness shows that when the initial participation willingness of aquaculture enterprise and service organization is low, the government needs to take measures such as policy promotion and financial subsidy incentives to enhance the participation enthusiasm of both parties. Therefore, the government’s initial participation willingness will increase in the short term. However, as the participation enthusiasm of aquaculture enterprise and service organization increases and the cooperation model between the two parties continues to improve, government intervention will gradually decrease.

      (3) Analysis of the impact of risk cost and risk coefficient shows that when the risk cost of deep-sea aquaculture is too high, aquaculture enterprise and service organization cannot form the motivation to participate due to the “loss aversion effect.” Government intervention may lead to the occurrence of “adverse selection,” resulting in government failure. When the proportion of risk borne by aquaculture enterprise and service organization is imbalanced, it will reduce the cooperation efficiency between the two parties and ultimately affect the evolution of the model.

      (4) Simulation analysis of cooperation benefit and distribution coefficient reveals the impact of the changing relative importance of “efficiency-equity” on the strategies of aquaculture enterprise and service organization in their cooperation. An increase in cooperation benefit can effectively reduce government intervention cost and enhance the role of market mechanism. However, when the distribution of cooperation benefit loses fairness, the increase in cooperation benefit will generate a reverse driving mechanism, causing a decrease in the enthusiasm of one party to participate.

      (5) The phenomenon of double failure of government and market in the analysis of the combined impact of cost and government intervention is primarily due to the government implementing erroneous economic policies that violate market principles. In the context of excessively high cost in deep-sea aquaculture, the focus should be on cost reduction rather than blindly increasing subsidy. This rigid government economic policy not only fails to enhance the efficiency of promoting and applying deep-sea aquaculture but also exacerbates the dependency of aquaculture enterprise and service organization on subsidy, leading to a shift in the motivation for engaging in deep-sea aquaculture from profit-driven to policy arbitrage-driven.

      In summary, compared with existing research, the conclusion reached in this study, that “policy guidance should be strengthened and the government should play a leading role in promoting the application of deep-sea aquaculture,” corresponds with the existing research mentioned in the introduction, which confirms the validity of the conclusion reached in this study. Unlike previous studies, this study also obtained other findings through evolutionary game model analysis: (1) Due to the high risk and high cost characteristics of deep-sea aquaculture, government intervention is limited, and the role of market mechanism should be fully utilized. (2) Although profit is an important factor in the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture, since deep-sea aquaculture requires the joint efforts of aquaculture enterprise and service organization, it is more important to establish a fair profit distribution and risk-sharing mechanism. (3) The focus of promoting deep-sea aquaculture lies in reducing cost, and blind government intervention policy will not play a positive role. This research proposes concepts such as a “government phased intervention mechanism,” a “risk-sharing and profit-sharing mechanism,” and an “efficiency-equity dynamic relationship” with the aim of providing scientific basis for government policy-making, guiding cooperation between aquaculture enterprise and service organization, and warning of policy failure risk. This study aims to break through the bottlenecks in the promotion of deep-sea aquaculture, increase the supply of high-quality animal protein, empower the construction of blue granaries, and ensure global food security and human nutritional needs.

      However, this study still has certain limitations. It only considers the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture under the participation of the government, aquaculture enterprise, and service organization, without considering the subsequent circulation, processing, and sales links. Therefore, introducing processing enterprise, logistics enterprise, consumer feedback, and other game subjects or influencing factors will be the direction of future research.

      Policy recommendation

      Based on the findings above, the study makes the following policy recommendations:

      (1) Increase the initial motivation of deep-sea aquaculture among all participants. As an emerging industry, deep-sea aquaculture is not well understood in most international countries, and its market prospects are still unknown. Therefore, the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture should firstly improve the motivation of aquaculture enterprise and service organization. Firstly, policy propaganda on deep-sea aquaculture should be strengthened to enhance social understanding of deep-sea aquaculture through sound top-level design and policy releases, so as to inject strong motivation into the enterprise. Secondly, since aquaculture enterprise and service organization are greatly affected by information asymmetry in their initial decision making, an information and technology exchange platform for deep-sea aquaculture should be established to promote information sharing and technology exchange between aquaculture enterprise and service organization.

      (2) Establish a reasonable government intervention system. Government intervention is very important to the promotion and application of deep-sea aquaculture. However, in view of the high-cost characteristics of deep-sea aquaculture, the government should fully respect the rule of the market and take into account its own cost problems, and adopt reasonable intervention measures. First, it is necessary to draw on Norway’s tiered licensing and innovation incentive system to establish an innovative license for deep-sea aquaculture, allowing aquaculture enterprise to apply for excess aquaculture biomass quotas and expand the scale of aquaculture to meet the high-tech and high-risk demands of deep-sea aquaculture. Secondly, in terms of subsidy policies, drawing inspiration from the European Union’s Blue Economy Investment Fund and Blue Carbon Credit Mechanism, a dedicated fund should be established for deep-sea aquaculture. This fund would provide specialized subsidy support for deep-sea aquaculture operations and allow carbon credit revenues to offset a portion of marine area usage fees. Concurrently, the government should establish a subsidy evaluation mechanism to assess subsidy eligibility based on clearly defined subsidy guidelines, standards, and upper limits. Finally, in terms of regulation, cooperation between aquaculture enterprise and service organization supervision should be strengthened, with the latter participating in contract signing as a “notary” and promptly imposing penalties on parties that violate contracts. At the same time, control and tracking of the use of special funds should be strengthened. While maintaining efficiency, the approval process for deep-sea funding support should be strictly enforced to prevent the misuse of national subsidy funds.

      (3) Promote cost reduction and improve the risk-sharing and benefit-sharing mechanism. As a high-cost project, the cost of deep-sea aquaculture is an important factor hindering the participating entities. Therefore, in the process of promoting citation, emphasis should be placed on achieving cost reduction. Firstly, the establishment of the deep-sea aquaculture insurance system should be strengthened, and a third-party organization should be involved to assess the risk of deep-sea aquaculture and formulate the insurance policy. At the same time, the government should use its own credibility as a guarantor to reduce the difficulty of the participating parties in obtaining insurance and loans, so as to provide the participating parties with a complete risk guarantee and reduce the risk cost. Secondly, it should actively strengthen the self-research and development of deep-sea aquaculture technology and equipment, promote the transformation of scientific and technological achievements, and improve the legal system of intellectual property rights and patent protection of deep-sea aquaculture, so as to not only reduce the risk cost of service organization, but also enhance the independent innovation ability of deep-sea aquaculture. In terms of risk sharing and benefit sharing, the government should act as a third party to assess the costs and benefits of each party in the process of cooperation in a fair and impartial manner, and determine the criteria for risk sharing and benefit sharing according to the contributions of each party.

      Data availability statement

      The original contributions presented in the study are included in the article/supplementary material, further inquiries can be directed to the corresponding author.

      Author contributions

      YM: Writing – review & editing, Writing – original draft. YZ: Writing – original draft, Writing – review & editing.

      Funding

      The author(s) declare that financial support was received for the research and/or publication of this article. This study was supported by the National Natural Science Foundation of China (42176218) and the Qingdao Science and Technology Innovation Strategic Research Program (25–1-4-zlyj-7-zhc).

      Conflict of interest

      The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.

      Generative AI statement

      The authors declare that no Gen AI was used in the creation of this manuscript.

      Publisher’s note

      All claims expressed in this article are solely those of the authors and do not necessarily represent those of their affiliated organizations, or those of the publisher, the editors and the reviewers. Any product that may be evaluated in this article, or claim that may be made by its manufacturer, is not guaranteed or endorsed by the publisher.

      References KapetskyJ. M. JoseA. M. JennessJ. 2013 A global assessment of offshore mariculture potential from a spatial perspective. FAO fisheries and aquaculture technical paper, 549, I BuckBH LanganR. Aquaculture perspective of multi-use sites in the open ocean: the untapped potential for marine resources in the anthropocene Springer Nature (2017). Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Development of China (2023) Opinions on accelerating the development of deep-sea aquaculture. Ministry of Agriculture and Rural Affairs of China. FAO (2022). Fisheries and aquaculture statistics. Global Aquaculture and Fisheries Production 1950–2020 (Fishstatj). FAO. (2022). The state of world fisheries and aquaculture. Towards blue transformation. XuJ HanLM YinW. Research on the ecologicalization efficiency of mariculture industry in China and its influencing factors. Mar Policy. (2022) 137:104935. doi: 10.1016/j.marpol.2021.104935 MerinoG BarangeM BlanchardJL HarleJ HolmesR AllenI . Can marine fisheries and aquaculture meet fish demand from a growing human population in a changing climate? Glob Environ Change. (2012) 22:795806. doi: 10.1016/j.gloenvcha.2012.03.003 KoričanM VladimirN BujasT VukićM. Comparative analysis of traditional and deep sea aquaculture In: International Symposium on Fisheries and Aquatic Sciences (2023). 745. ZhangY LiMF FangXH. Efficiency analysis of China Deep-Sea cage aquaculture based on the SBM–Malmquist model. Fishes. (2023) 8:529. doi: 10.3390/fishes8100529 ZhaoYX ZhangJH QuDP YangYY WuWG SunK . Benthic environmental impact of deep sea cage and traditional cage fish mariculture in Yellow Sea, China. Aquac Res. (2021) 52:502233. doi: 10.1111/are.15374 YinW HanLM XuJJ GuoAH. Discussion on key issues in the development of China’s deep-sea aquaculture industry chain: a case study of salmon farming in the Yellow Sea cold water mass. China Fish Econ. (2023) 41:2533. YinW YuHJ QiuRS HanLM. China’s food and nutrition security in the context of land-sea integration. Resour Sci. (2022) 44:67486. YuHJ NiuM HanLM. Development strategies for China’s “blue granary” and industrial chain restructuring. Agric Econ Issues. (2019) 11:7281. doi: 10.13246/j.cnki.iae.2019.11.007 FroehlichHE SmithA GentryRR HalpernBS. Offshore aquaculture: I know it when I see it. Front Mar Sci. (2017) 4:154. doi: 10.3389/fmars.2017.00154 GreakerM VormedalI RosendalK. Environmental policy and innovation in Norwegian fish farming: resolving the sea lice problem. Mar Policy. (2020) 117:103942. doi: 10.1016/j.marpol.2020.103942 AfewerkiS OsmundsenT OlsenMS StørkersenKV MisundA ThorvaldsenT. Innovation policy in the Norwegian aquaculture industry: reshaping aquaculture production innovation networks. Mar Policy. (2023) 152:105624. doi: 10.1016/j.marpol.2023.105624 FøreHM ThorvaldsenT OsmundsenTC Moe FøreH AscheF TveteråsR . Technological innovations promoting sustainable salmon (Salmo salar) aquaculture in Norway. Aquac Rep. (2022) 24:101115. doi: 10.1016/j.aqrep.2022.101115 HuanXM ShanJZ HanLM SongHM. Research on the efficacy and effect assessment of deep-sea aquaculture policies in China: quantitative analysis of policy texts based on the period 2004–2022. Mar Policy. (2024) 160:105963. doi: 10.1016/j.marpol.2023.105963 WuKK LiQS HuangHP ChenKL. Deep-sea aquaculture progress and development measures in China. Marine Dev Manag. (2022) 39:118. doi: 10.20016/j.cnki.hykfygl.20221014.001 ZhangZZ LiuYY. The status quo, issues and foreign experiences of Deep Sea aquaculture equipment of China. Int Conf Soc Sci. (2018):3737. LinM. Development of large-scale deep-sea aquaculture: problems, models and realisation paths. Manag World. (2022) 38:3960. doi: 10.19744/j.cnki.11-1235/f.2022.0177 GaoS. Development direction and suggestion of deep-sea aquaculture equipment and facilities. China Water Transport. (2023) 23:145. LiuHM BiWJ WuP. Current situation and suggestions on the development of deep-sea aquaculture in Weihai city. Aquaculture. (2023) 44:6162+68. LinJM. Current situation and suggestions for the development of equipment-based deep-sea aquaculture in Fujian Province. Fish Modernis. (2024) 51:118. ChenCP LiuHF HuangY YangJ LiangXY ZhangCB . Numerical simulation of mechanical characteristics of a metal net for deep-sea aquaculture. J Ocean Univ China. (2019) 18:127381. doi: 10.1007/s11802-019-4079-z TaoYW ZhuRQ GuJY LiZY ZhangZY XuXS. Experimental and numerical investigation of the hydrodynamic response of an aquaculture vessel. Ocean Eng. (2023) 279:114505. doi: 10.1016/j.oceaneng.2023.114505 HouHM DongGH XuTJ. Analysis of probabilistic fatigue damage of mooring system for offshore fish cage considering long-term stochastic wave conditions. Ships Offshore Struct. (2020) 17:398409. doi: 10.1080/17445302.2020.1834752 LiG YaoZD HuY LianAJ YuanTP PangGL . Deep learning-based fish detection using above-water infrared camera for deep-sea aquaculture: a comparison study. Sensors. (2024) 24:2430. doi: 10.3390/s24082430, PMID: 38676049 WangPH ChenZG FengYK. Many-objective optimization for a deep-sea aquaculture vessel based on an improved RBF neural network surrogate model. J Mar Sci Technol. (2021) 26:582605. doi: 10.1007/s00773-020-00756-z YuanXN MiaoQM ZouCF WangCY. Numerical study on aquaculture environment in deep-sea cage with waves. ISOPE Int Ocean Polar Engi Conf. (2022) ZhangQF WangLK ChenMJ. Construction technology for large-scale frame-type deep-sea aquaculture cages. Marine Dev Manag. (2024) 41:8390. doi: 10.20016/j.cnki.hykfygl.20240923.001 ChenSX SuYQ HongWS. Aquaculture of the large yellow croaker. Aquac China. (2018):297308. doi: 10.1002/9781119120759.ch3_10 FanF ZhengJL LiuH CuiMC. Assessment of the carbon footprint of large yellow croaker farming on the aquaculture vessel in deep sea in China. J Mar Sci Eng. (2024) 12:693. doi: 10.3390/jmse12050693 LiTJ GuoDK ShenY BaoJJ JinL. Comparative analysis of bacterial communities in the sediment and seawater environments from marine large yellow croaker cages (Zhejiang coast, China). Front Mar Sci. (2022) 9:963242. doi: 10.3389/fmars.2022.963242 LiYY ZhenXW ZhuYS HuangY ZhangLX LiHX. Conceptual design and structural performance analysis of an innovative deep-sea aquaculture platform. J Mar Sci Eng. (2024) 12:1058. doi: 10.3390/jmse12071058 FøreM AlverMO FrankK AlfredsenJA. Advanced technology in aquaculture–smart feeding in marine fish farms. Cham: Springer (2023). YuanXN WangCY MiaoQM ZouCF. Investigation on quantitative evaluation method for feed diffusion effect in deep-sea aquaculture cages. Ocean Eng. (2024) 295:116759. doi: 10.1016/j.oceaneng.2024.116759 TraulsenA GlynatsiNE. The future of theoretical evolutionary game theory. Philos Trans R Soc B. (2023) 378:20210508. doi: 10.1098/rstb.2021.0508, PMID: 36934760 GaoXL LuWW HuJ ZhangXL. Current status and challenges of deep-sea aquaculture industrialization in China: a study based on Liaoning, Shandong, Guangdong, and Hainan. Marine Econ. (2025) 15:1123. doi: 10.19426/j.cnki.cn12-1424/p.2025.02.002 NingJ XiongL. Analysis of the dynamic evolution process of the digital transformation of renewable energy enterprises based on the cooperative and evolutionary game model. Energy. (2024) 288:129758. doi: 10.1016/j.energy.2023.129758 WangEK ChenCM YiuSM HassanMM AlrubaianmM FortinoG. Incentive evolutionary game model for opportunistic social networks. Futur Gener Comput Syst. (2020) 102:1429. ZhuLL RongJM ZhangSY. Evolutionary game theory and simulation analysis of three-party interaction in drug safety and quality supervision under government reward and punishment mechanisms. Chin J Manage Sci. (2021) 29:5567. doi: 10.16381/j.cnki.issn1003-207x.2019.0481
      ‘Oh, my dear Thomas, you haven’t heard the terrible news then?’ she said. ‘I thought you would be sure to have seen it placarded somewhere. Alice went straight to her room, and I haven’t seen her since, though I repeatedly knocked at the door, which she has locked on the inside, and I’m sure it’s most unnatural of her not to let her own mother comfort her. It all happened in a moment: I have always said those great motor-cars shouldn’t be allowed to career about the streets, especially when they are all paved with cobbles as they are at Easton Haven, which are{331} so slippery when it’s wet. He slipped, and it went over him in a moment.’ My thanks were few and awkward, for there still hung to the missive a basting thread, and it was as warm as a nestling bird. I bent low--everybody was emotional in those days--kissed the fragrant thing, thrust it into my bosom, and blushed worse than Camille. "What, the Corner House victim? Is that really a fact?" "My dear child, I don't look upon it in that light at all. The child gave our picturesque friend a certain distinction--'My husband is dead, and this is my only child,' and all that sort of thing. It pays in society." leave them on the steps of a foundling asylum in order to insure [See larger version] Interoffice guff says you're planning definite moves on your own, J. O., and against some opposition. Is the Colonel so poor or so grasping—or what? Albert could not speak, for he felt as if his brains and teeth were rattling about inside his head. The rest of[Pg 188] the family hunched together by the door, the boys gaping idiotically, the girls in tears. "Now you're married." The host was called in, and unlocked a drawer in which they were deposited. The galleyman, with visible reluctance, arrayed himself in the garments, and he was observed to shudder more than once during the investiture of the dead man's apparel. HoME香京julia种子在线播放 ENTER NUMBET 0016ebcfc.com.cn
      www.jouetie.net.cn
      ektcbg.com.cn
      jx618.com.cn
      www.icoebuy.com.cn
      fdukcg.com.cn
      two-l.com.cn
      www.nmqx.com.cn
      sytgroup.com.cn
      qschain.com.cn
      处女被大鸡巴操 强奸乱伦小说图片 俄罗斯美女爱爱图 调教强奸学生 亚洲女的穴 夜来香图片大全 美女性强奸电影 手机版色中阁 男性人体艺术素描图 16p成人 欧美性爱360 电影区 亚洲电影 欧美电影 经典三级 偷拍自拍 动漫电影 乱伦电影 变态另类 全部电 类似狠狠鲁的网站 黑吊操白逼图片 韩国黄片种子下载 操逼逼逼逼逼 人妻 小说 p 偷拍10幼女自慰 极品淫水很多 黄色做i爱 日本女人人体电影快播看 大福国小 我爱肏屄美女 mmcrwcom 欧美多人性交图片 肥臀乱伦老头舔阴帝 d09a4343000019c5 西欧人体艺术b xxoo激情短片 未成年人的 插泰国人夭图片 第770弾み1 24p 日本美女性 交动态 eee色播 yantasythunder 操无毛少女屄 亚洲图片你懂的女人 鸡巴插姨娘 特级黄 色大片播 左耳影音先锋 冢本友希全集 日本人体艺术绿色 我爱被舔逼 内射 幼 美阴图 喷水妹子高潮迭起 和后妈 操逼 美女吞鸡巴 鸭个自慰 中国女裸名单 操逼肥臀出水换妻 色站裸体义术 中国行上的漏毛美女叫什么 亚洲妹性交图 欧美美女人裸体人艺照 成人色妹妹直播 WWW_JXCT_COM r日本女人性淫乱 大胆人艺体艺图片 女同接吻av 碰碰哥免费自拍打炮 艳舞写真duppid1 88电影街拍视频 日本自拍做爱qvod 实拍美女性爱组图 少女高清av 浙江真实乱伦迅雷 台湾luanlunxiaoshuo 洛克王国宠物排行榜 皇瑟电影yy频道大全 红孩儿连连看 阴毛摄影 大胆美女写真人体艺术摄影 和风骚三个媳妇在家做爱 性爱办公室高清 18p2p木耳 大波撸影音 大鸡巴插嫩穴小说 一剧不超两个黑人 阿姨诱惑我快播 幼香阁千叶县小学生 少女妇女被狗强奸 曰人体妹妹 十二岁性感幼女 超级乱伦qvod 97爱蜜桃ccc336 日本淫妇阴液 av海量资源999 凤凰影视成仁 辰溪四中艳照门照片 先锋模特裸体展示影片 成人片免费看 自拍百度云 肥白老妇女 女爱人体图片 妈妈一女穴 星野美夏 日本少女dachidu 妹子私处人体图片 yinmindahuitang 舔无毛逼影片快播 田莹疑的裸体照片 三级电影影音先锋02222 妻子被外国老头操 观月雏乃泥鳅 韩国成人偷拍自拍图片 强奸5一9岁幼女小说 汤姆影院av图片 妹妹人艺体图 美女大驱 和女友做爱图片自拍p 绫川まどか在线先锋 那么嫩的逼很少见了 小女孩做爱 处女好逼连连看图图 性感美女在家做爱 近距离抽插骚逼逼 黑屌肏金毛屄 日韩av美少女 看喝尿尿小姐日逼色色色网图片 欧美肛交新视频 美女吃逼逼 av30线上免费 伊人在线三级经典 新视觉影院t6090影院 最新淫色电影网址 天龙影院远古手机版 搞老太影院 插进美女的大屁股里 私人影院加盟费用 www258dd 求一部电影里面有一个二猛哥 深肛交 日本萌妹子人体艺术写真图片 插入屄眼 美女的木奶 中文字幕黄色网址影视先锋 九号女神裸 和骚人妻偷情 和潘晓婷做爱 国模大尺度蜜桃 欧美大逼50p 西西人体成人 李宗瑞继母做爱原图物处理 nianhuawang 男鸡巴的视屏 � 97免费色伦电影 好色网成人 大姨子先锋 淫荡巨乳美女教师妈妈 性nuexiaoshuo WWW36YYYCOM 长春继续给力进屋就操小女儿套干破内射对白淫荡 农夫激情社区 日韩无码bt 欧美美女手掰嫩穴图片 日本援交偷拍自拍 入侵者日本在线播放 亚洲白虎偷拍自拍 常州高见泽日屄 寂寞少妇自卫视频 人体露逼图片 多毛外国老太 变态乱轮手机在线 淫荡妈妈和儿子操逼 伦理片大奶少女 看片神器最新登入地址sqvheqi345com账号群 麻美学姐无头 圣诞老人射小妞和强奸小妞动话片 亚洲AV女老师 先锋影音欧美成人资源 33344iucoom zV天堂电影网 宾馆美女打炮视频 色五月丁香五月magnet 嫂子淫乱小说 张歆艺的老公 吃奶男人视频在线播放 欧美色图男女乱伦 avtt2014ccvom 性插色欲香影院 青青草撸死你青青草 99热久久第一时间 激情套图卡通动漫 幼女裸聊做爱口交 日本女人被强奸乱伦 草榴社区快播 2kkk正在播放兽骑 啊不要人家小穴都湿了 www猎奇影视 A片www245vvcomwwwchnrwhmhzcn 搜索宜春院av wwwsee78co 逼奶鸡巴插 好吊日AV在线视频19gancom 熟女伦乱图片小说 日本免费av无码片在线开苞 鲁大妈撸到爆 裸聊官网 德国熟女xxx 新不夜城论坛首页手机 女虐男网址 男女做爱视频华为网盘 激情午夜天亚洲色图 内裤哥mangent 吉沢明歩制服丝袜WWWHHH710COM 屌逼在线试看 人体艺体阿娇艳照 推荐一个可以免费看片的网站如果被QQ拦截请复制链接在其它浏览器打开xxxyyy5comintr2a2cb551573a2b2e 欧美360精品粉红鲍鱼 教师调教第一页 聚美屋精品图 中韩淫乱群交 俄罗斯撸撸片 把鸡巴插进小姨子的阴道 干干AV成人网 aolasoohpnbcn www84ytom 高清大量潮喷www27dyycom 宝贝开心成人 freefronvideos人母 嫩穴成人网gggg29com 逼着舅妈给我口交肛交彩漫画 欧美色色aV88wwwgangguanscom 老太太操逼自拍视频 777亚洲手机在线播放 有没有夫妻3p小说 色列漫画淫女 午间色站导航 欧美成人处女色大图 童颜巨乳亚洲综合 桃色性欲草 色眯眯射逼 无码中文字幕塞外青楼这是一个 狂日美女老师人妻 爱碰网官网 亚洲图片雅蠛蝶 快播35怎么搜片 2000XXXX电影 新谷露性家庭影院 深深候dvd播放 幼齿用英语怎么说 不雅伦理无需播放器 国外淫荡图片 国外网站幼幼嫩网址 成年人就去色色视频快播 我鲁日日鲁老老老我爱 caoshaonvbi 人体艺术avav 性感性色导航 韩国黄色哥来嫖网站 成人网站美逼 淫荡熟妇自拍 欧美色惰图片 北京空姐透明照 狼堡免费av视频 www776eom 亚洲无码av欧美天堂网男人天堂 欧美激情爆操 a片kk266co 色尼姑成人极速在线视频 国语家庭系列 蒋雯雯 越南伦理 色CC伦理影院手机版 99jbbcom 大鸡巴舅妈 国产偷拍自拍淫荡对话视频 少妇春梦射精 开心激动网 自拍偷牌成人 色桃隐 撸狗网性交视频 淫荡的三位老师 伦理电影wwwqiuxia6commqiuxia6com 怡春院分站 丝袜超短裙露脸迅雷下载 色制服电影院 97超碰好吊色男人 yy6080理论在线宅男日韩福利大全 大嫂丝袜 500人群交手机在线 5sav 偷拍熟女吧 口述我和妹妹的欲望 50p电脑版 wwwavtttcon 3p3com 伦理无码片在线看 欧美成人电影图片岛国性爱伦理电影 先锋影音AV成人欧美 我爱好色 淫电影网 WWW19MMCOM 玛丽罗斯3d同人动画h在线看 动漫女孩裸体 超级丝袜美腿乱伦 1919gogo欣赏 大色逼淫色 www就是撸 激情文学网好骚 A级黄片免费 xedd5com 国内的b是黑的 快播美国成年人片黄 av高跟丝袜视频 上原保奈美巨乳女教师在线观看 校园春色都市激情fefegancom 偷窥自拍XXOO 搜索看马操美女 人本女优视频 日日吧淫淫 人妻巨乳影院 美国女子性爱学校 大肥屁股重口味 啪啪啪啊啊啊不要 操碰 japanfreevideoshome国产 亚州淫荡老熟女人体 伦奸毛片免费在线看 天天影视se 樱桃做爱视频 亚卅av在线视频 x奸小说下载 亚洲色图图片在线 217av天堂网 东方在线撸撸-百度 幼幼丝袜集 灰姑娘的姐姐 青青草在线视频观看对华 86papa路con 亚洲1AV 综合图片2区亚洲 美国美女大逼电影 010插插av成人网站 www色comwww821kxwcom 播乐子成人网免费视频在线观看 大炮撸在线影院 ,www4KkKcom 野花鲁最近30部 wwwCC213wapwww2233ww2download 三客优最新地址 母亲让儿子爽的无码视频 全国黄色片子 欧美色图美国十次 超碰在线直播 性感妖娆操 亚洲肉感熟女色图 a片A毛片管看视频 8vaa褋芯屑 333kk 川岛和津实视频 在线母子乱伦对白 妹妹肥逼五月 亚洲美女自拍 老婆在我面前小说 韩国空姐堪比情趣内衣 干小姐综合 淫妻色五月 添骚穴 WM62COM 23456影视播放器 成人午夜剧场 尼姑福利网 AV区亚洲AV欧美AV512qucomwwwc5508com 经典欧美骚妇 震动棒露出 日韩丝袜美臀巨乳在线 av无限吧看 就去干少妇 色艺无间正面是哪集 校园春色我和老师做爱 漫画夜色 天海丽白色吊带 黄色淫荡性虐小说 午夜高清播放器 文20岁女性荫道口图片 热国产热无码热有码 2015小明发布看看算你色 百度云播影视 美女肏屄屄乱轮小说 家族舔阴AV影片 邪恶在线av有码 父女之交 关于处女破处的三级片 极品护士91在线 欧美虐待女人视频的网站 享受老太太的丝袜 aaazhibuo 8dfvodcom成人 真实自拍足交 群交男女猛插逼 妓女爱爱动态 lin35com是什么网站 abp159 亚洲色图偷拍自拍乱伦熟女抠逼自慰 朝国三级篇 淫三国幻想 免费的av小电影网站 日本阿v视频免费按摩师 av750c0m 黄色片操一下 巨乳少女车震在线观看 操逼 免费 囗述情感一乱伦岳母和女婿 WWW_FAMITSU_COM 偷拍中国少妇在公车被操视频 花也真衣论理电影 大鸡鸡插p洞 新片欧美十八岁美少 进击的巨人神thunderftp 西方美女15p 深圳哪里易找到老女人玩视频 在线成人有声小说 365rrr 女尿图片 我和淫荡的小姨做爱 � 做爱技术体照 淫妇性爱 大学生私拍b 第四射狠狠射小说 色中色成人av社区 和小姨子乱伦肛交 wwwppp62com 俄罗斯巨乳人体艺术 骚逼阿娇 汤芳人体图片大胆 大胆人体艺术bb私处 性感大胸骚货 哪个网站幼女的片多 日本美女本子把 色 五月天 婷婷 快播 美女 美穴艺术 色百合电影导航 大鸡巴用力 孙悟空操美少女战士 狠狠撸美女手掰穴图片 古代女子与兽类交 沙耶香套图 激情成人网区 暴风影音av播放 动漫女孩怎么插第3个 mmmpp44 黑木麻衣无码ed2k 淫荡学姐少妇 乱伦操少女屄 高中性爱故事 骚妹妹爱爱图网 韩国模特剪长发 大鸡巴把我逼日了 中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片中国张柏芝做爱片 大胆女人下体艺术图片 789sss 影音先锋在线国内情侣野外性事自拍普通话对白 群撸图库 闪现君打阿乐 ady 小说 插入表妹嫩穴小说 推荐成人资源 网络播放器 成人台 149大胆人体艺术 大屌图片 骚美女成人av 春暖花开春色性吧 女亭婷五月 我上了同桌的姐姐 恋夜秀场主播自慰视频 yzppp 屄茎 操屄女图 美女鲍鱼大特写 淫乱的日本人妻山口玲子 偷拍射精图 性感美女人体艺木图片 种马小说完本 免费电影院 骑士福利导航导航网站 骚老婆足交 国产性爱一级电影 欧美免费成人花花性都 欧美大肥妞性爱视频 家庭乱伦网站快播 偷拍自拍国产毛片 金发美女也用大吊来开包 缔D杏那 yentiyishu人体艺术ytys WWWUUKKMCOM 女人露奶 � 苍井空露逼 老荡妇高跟丝袜足交 偷偷和女友的朋友做爱迅雷 做爱七十二尺 朱丹人体合成 麻腾由纪妃 帅哥撸播种子图 鸡巴插逼动态图片 羙国十次啦中文 WWW137AVCOM 神斗片欧美版华语 有气质女人人休艺术 由美老师放屁电影 欧美女人肉肏图片 白虎种子快播 国产自拍90后女孩 美女在床上疯狂嫩b 饭岛爱最后之作 幼幼强奸摸奶 色97成人动漫 两性性爱打鸡巴插逼 新视觉影院4080青苹果影院 嗯好爽插死我了 阴口艺术照 李宗瑞电影qvod38 爆操舅母 亚洲色图七七影院 被大鸡巴操菊花 怡红院肿么了 成人极品影院删除 欧美性爱大图色图强奸乱 欧美女子与狗随便性交 苍井空的bt种子无码 熟女乱伦长篇小说 大色虫 兽交幼女影音先锋播放 44aad be0ca93900121f9b 先锋天耗ばさ无码 欧毛毛女三级黄色片图 干女人黑木耳照 日本美女少妇嫩逼人体艺术 sesechangchang 色屄屄网 久久撸app下载 色图色噜 美女鸡巴大奶 好吊日在线视频在线观看 透明丝袜脚偷拍自拍 中山怡红院菜单 wcwwwcom下载 骑嫂子 亚洲大色妣 成人故事365ahnet 丝袜家庭教mp4 幼交肛交 妹妹撸撸大妈 日本毛爽 caoprom超碰在email 关于中国古代偷窥的黄片 第一会所老熟女下载 wwwhuangsecome 狼人干综合新地址HD播放 变态儿子强奸乱伦图 强奸电影名字 2wwwer37com 日本毛片基地一亚洲AVmzddcxcn 暗黑圣经仙桃影院 37tpcocn 持月真由xfplay 好吊日在线视频三级网 我爱背入李丽珍 电影师傅床戏在线观看 96插妹妹sexsex88com 豪放家庭在线播放 桃花宝典极夜著豆瓜网 安卓系统播放神器 美美网丝袜诱惑 人人干全免费视频xulawyercn av无插件一本道 全国色五月 操逼电影小说网 good在线wwwyuyuelvcom www18avmmd 撸波波影视无插件 伊人幼女成人电影 会看射的图片 小明插看看 全裸美女扒开粉嫩b 国人自拍性交网站 萝莉白丝足交本子 七草ちとせ巨乳视频 摇摇晃晃的成人电影 兰桂坊成社人区小说www68kqcom 舔阴论坛 久撸客一撸客色国内外成人激情在线 明星门 欧美大胆嫩肉穴爽大片 www牛逼插 性吧星云 少妇性奴的屁眼 人体艺术大胆mscbaidu1imgcn 最新久久色色成人版 l女同在线 小泽玛利亚高潮图片搜索 女性裸b图 肛交bt种子 最热门有声小说 人间添春色 春色猜谜字 樱井莉亚钢管舞视频 小泽玛利亚直美6p 能用的h网 还能看的h网 bl动漫h网 开心五月激 东京热401 男色女色第四色酒色网 怎么下载黄色小说 黄色小说小栽 和谐图城 乐乐影院 色哥导航 特色导航 依依社区 爱窝窝在线 色狼谷成人 91porn 包要你射电影 色色3A丝袜 丝袜妹妹淫网 爱色导航(荐) 好男人激情影院 坏哥哥 第七色 色久久 人格分裂 急先锋 撸撸射中文网 第一会所综合社区 91影院老师机 东方成人激情 怼莪影院吹潮 老鸭窝伊人无码不卡无码一本道 av女柳晶电影 91天生爱风流作品 深爱激情小说私房婷婷网 擼奶av 567pao 里番3d一家人野外 上原在线电影 水岛津实透明丝袜 1314酒色 网旧网俺也去 0855影院 在线无码私人影院 搜索 国产自拍 神马dy888午夜伦理达达兔 农民工黄晓婷 日韩裸体黑丝御姐 屈臣氏的燕窝面膜怎么样つぼみ晶エリーの早漏チ○ポ强化合宿 老熟女人性视频 影音先锋 三上悠亚ol 妹妹影院福利片 hhhhhhhhsxo 午夜天堂热的国产 强奸剧场 全裸香蕉视频无码 亚欧伦理视频 秋霞为什么给封了 日本在线视频空天使 日韩成人aⅴ在线 日本日屌日屄导航视频 在线福利视频 日本推油无码av magnet 在线免费视频 樱井梨吮东 日本一本道在线无码DVD 日本性感诱惑美女做爱阴道流水视频 日本一级av 汤姆avtom在线视频 台湾佬中文娱乐线20 阿v播播下载 橙色影院 奴隶少女护士cg视频 汤姆在线影院无码 偷拍宾馆 业面紧急生级访问 色和尚有线 厕所偷拍一族 av女l 公交色狼优酷视频 裸体视频AV 人与兽肉肉网 董美香ol 花井美纱链接 magnet 西瓜影音 亚洲 自拍 日韩女优欧美激情偷拍自拍 亚洲成年人免费视频 荷兰免费成人电影 深喉呕吐XXⅩX 操石榴在线视频 天天色成人免费视频 314hu四虎 涩久免费视频在线观看 成人电影迅雷下载 能看见整个奶子的香蕉影院 水菜丽百度影音 gwaz079百度云 噜死你们资源站 主播走光视频合集迅雷下载 thumbzilla jappen 精品Av 古川伊织star598在线 假面女皇vip在线视频播放 国产自拍迷情校园 啪啪啪公寓漫画 日本阿AV 黄色手机电影 欧美在线Av影院 华裔电击女神91在线 亚洲欧美专区 1日本1000部免费视频 开放90后 波多野结衣 东方 影院av 页面升级紧急访问每天正常更新 4438Xchengeren 老炮色 a k福利电影 色欲影视色天天视频 高老庄aV 259LUXU-683 magnet 手机在线电影 国产区 欧美激情人人操网 国产 偷拍 直播 日韩 国内外激情在线视频网给 站长统计一本道人妻 光棍影院被封 紫竹铃取汁 ftp 狂插空姐嫩 xfplay 丈夫面前 穿靴子伪街 XXOO视频在线免费 大香蕉道久在线播放 电棒漏电嗨过头 充气娃能看下毛和洞吗 夫妻牲交 福利云点墦 yukun瑟妃 疯狂交换女友 国产自拍26页 腐女资源 百度云 日本DVD高清无码视频 偷拍,自拍AV伦理电影 A片小视频福利站。 大奶肥婆自拍偷拍图片 交配伊甸园 超碰在线视频自拍偷拍国产 小热巴91大神 rctd 045 类似于A片 超美大奶大学生美女直播被男友操 男友问 你的衣服怎么脱掉的 亚洲女与黑人群交视频一 在线黄涩 木内美保步兵番号 鸡巴插入欧美美女的b舒服 激情在线国产自拍日韩欧美 国语福利小视频在线观看 作爱小视颍 潮喷合集丝袜无码mp4 做爱的无码高清视频 牛牛精品 伊aⅤ在线观看 savk12 哥哥搞在线播放 在线电一本道影 一级谍片 250pp亚洲情艺中心,88 欧美一本道九色在线一 wwwseavbacom色av吧 cos美女在线 欧美17,18ⅹⅹⅹ视频 自拍嫩逼 小电影在线观看网站 筱田优 贼 水电工 5358x视频 日本69式视频有码 b雪福利导航 韩国女主播19tvclub在线 操逼清晰视频 丝袜美女国产视频网址导航 水菜丽颜射房间 台湾妹中文娱乐网 风吟岛视频 口交 伦理 日本熟妇色五十路免费视频 A级片互舔 川村真矢Av在线观看 亚洲日韩av 色和尚国产自拍 sea8 mp4 aV天堂2018手机在线 免费版国产偷拍a在线播放 狠狠 婷婷 丁香 小视频福利在线观看平台 思妍白衣小仙女被邻居强上 萝莉自拍有水 4484新视觉 永久发布页 977成人影视在线观看 小清新影院在线观 小鸟酱后丝后入百度云 旋风魅影四级 香蕉影院小黄片免费看 性爱直播磁力链接 小骚逼第一色影院 性交流的视频 小雪小视频bd 小视频TV禁看视频 迷奸AV在线看 nba直播 任你在干线 汤姆影院在线视频国产 624u在线播放 成人 一级a做爰片就在线看狐狸视频 小香蕉AV视频 www182、com 腿模简小育 学生做爱视频 秘密搜查官 快播 成人福利网午夜 一级黄色夫妻录像片 直接看的gav久久播放器 国产自拍400首页 sm老爹影院 谁知道隔壁老王网址在线 综合网 123西瓜影音 米奇丁香 人人澡人人漠大学生 色久悠 夜色视频你今天寂寞了吗? 菲菲影视城美国 被抄的影院 变态另类 欧美 成人 国产偷拍自拍在线小说 不用下载安装就能看的吃男人鸡巴视频 插屄视频 大贯杏里播放 wwwhhh50 233若菜奈央 伦理片天海翼秘密搜查官 大香蕉在线万色屋视频 那种漫画小说你懂的 祥仔电影合集一区 那里可以看澳门皇冠酒店a片 色自啪 亚洲aV电影天堂 谷露影院ar toupaizaixian sexbj。com 毕业生 zaixian mianfei 朝桐光视频 成人短视频在线直接观看 陈美霖 沈阳音乐学院 导航女 www26yjjcom 1大尺度视频 开平虐女视频 菅野雪松协和影视在线视频 华人play在线视频bbb 鸡吧操屄视频 多啪啪免费视频 悠草影院 金兰策划网 (969) 橘佑金短视频 国内一极刺激自拍片 日本制服番号大全magnet 成人动漫母系 电脑怎么清理内存 黄色福利1000 dy88午夜 偷拍中学生洗澡磁力链接 花椒相机福利美女视频 站长推荐磁力下载 mp4 三洞轮流插视频 玉兔miki热舞视频 夜生活小视频 爆乳人妖小视频 国内网红主播自拍福利迅雷下载 不用app的裸裸体美女操逼视频 变态SM影片在线观看 草溜影院元气吧 - 百度 - 百度 波推全套视频 国产双飞集合ftp 日本在线AV网 笔国毛片 神马影院女主播是我的邻居 影音资源 激情乱伦电影 799pao 亚洲第一色第一影院 av视频大香蕉 老梁故事汇希斯莱杰 水中人体磁力链接 下载 大香蕉黄片免费看 济南谭崔 避开屏蔽的岛a片 草破福利 要看大鸡巴操小骚逼的人的视频 黑丝少妇影音先锋 欧美巨乳熟女磁力链接 美国黄网站色大全 伦蕉在线久播 极品女厕沟 激情五月bd韩国电影 混血美女自摸和男友激情啪啪自拍诱人呻吟福利视频 人人摸人人妻做人人看 44kknn 娸娸原网 伊人欧美 恋夜影院视频列表安卓青青 57k影院 如果电话亭 avi 插爆骚女精品自拍 青青草在线免费视频1769TV 令人惹火的邻家美眉 影音先锋 真人妹子被捅动态图 男人女人做完爱视频15 表姐合租两人共处一室晚上她竟爬上了我的床 性爱教学视频 北条麻妃bd在线播放版 国产老师和师生 magnet wwwcctv1024 女神自慰 ftp 女同性恋做激情视频 欧美大胆露阴视频 欧美无码影视 好女色在线观看 后入肥臀18p 百度影视屏福利 厕所超碰视频 强奸mp magnet 欧美妹aⅴ免费线上看 2016年妞干网视频 5手机在线福利 超在线最视频 800av:cOm magnet 欧美性爱免播放器在线播放 91大款肥汤的性感美乳90后邻家美眉趴着窗台后入啪啪 秋霞日本毛片网站 cheng ren 在线视频 上原亚衣肛门无码解禁影音先锋 美脚家庭教师在线播放 尤酷伦理片 熟女性生活视频在线观看 欧美av在线播放喷潮 194avav 凤凰AV成人 - 百度 kbb9999 AV片AV在线AV无码 爱爱视频高清免费观看 黄色男女操b视频 观看 18AV清纯视频在线播放平台 成人性爱视频久久操 女性真人生殖系统双性人视频 下身插入b射精视频 明星潜规测视频 mp4 免賛a片直播绪 国内 自己 偷拍 在线 国内真实偷拍 手机在线 国产主播户外勾在线 三桥杏奈高清无码迅雷下载 2五福电影院凸凹频频 男主拿鱼打女主,高宝宝 色哥午夜影院 川村まや痴汉 草溜影院费全过程免费 淫小弟影院在线视频 laohantuiche 啪啪啪喷潮XXOO视频 青娱乐成人国产 蓝沢润 一本道 亚洲青涩中文欧美 神马影院线理论 米娅卡莉法的av 在线福利65535 欧美粉色在线 欧美性受群交视频1在线播放 极品喷奶熟妇在线播放 变态另类无码福利影院92 天津小姐被偷拍 磁力下载 台湾三级电髟全部 丝袜美腿偷拍自拍 偷拍女生性行为图 妻子的乱伦 白虎少妇 肏婶骚屄 外国大妈会阴照片 美少女操屄图片 妹妹自慰11p 操老熟女的b 361美女人体 360电影院樱桃 爱色妹妹亚洲色图 性交卖淫姿势高清图片一级 欧美一黑对二白 大色网无毛一线天 射小妹网站 寂寞穴 西西人体模特苍井空 操的大白逼吧 骚穴让我操 拉好友干女朋友3p