Edited by: Alexander G. Ophir, Cornell University, United States
Reviewed by: Peter B. Gray, University of Nevada, Las Vegas, United States; Siobhan Mary Mattison, University of New Mexico, United States
This article was submitted to Behavioral and Evolutionary Ecology, a section of the journal Frontiers in Ecology and Evolution
This is an open-access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY). The use, distribution or reproduction in other forums is permitted, provided the original author(s) and the copyright owner(s) are credited and that the original publication in this journal is cited, in accordance with accepted academic practice. No use, distribution or reproduction is permitted which does not comply with these terms.
Human paternal investment, and that of many other species, is facultatively expressed and dependent on a diverse array of individual, social, and ecological conditions. Well-documented are the various ways in which men invest in offspring and the household. Specifically, local ecology structures pay-offs to male investment and has been shown to be an important predictor of the sexual division of labor. However, while variability in paternal investment has been well-characterized cross-culturally, plasticity within a group in response to changing socioecological conditions remains largely unstudied. To address this, we use recent economic development and market access to explore how changes in socioecology alter behavioral options for men and their resultant investment decisions. Among the monogamous Maya, we find that, associated with the introduction of novel subsistence opportunities and incentives for intensified paternal investment, fathers spend more time in the household, more time in domestic activities and more time interacting with their children. The changes in paternal investment documented here are largely contingent on four conditions: increased efficiency in subsistence brought about by mechanized farming, limited opportunities to engage in wage labor, increased opportunities to invest in offspring quality, and a monogamous mating system. Thus, Maya fathers appear to repurpose found time by furthering investment in their families.
香京julia种子在线播放
Across human societies, men and women typically engage in different yet complementary patterns of parental investment (Murdock and Provost,
Local ecology, paternity certainty, and opportunities for mating effort have all been shown to be important determinants of paternal involvement because they generally structure pay-offs to male investment across environments (e.g., Marlowe,
Social monogamy is relatively uncommon across mammals (3–9% of species; Kleiman,
Obligate and elevated reproductive costs among females (e.g., gestation, lactation) are commonly referenced to explain the preponderance of maternal care across mammalian taxa (Trivers,
Under certain circumstances, monogamy can increase male fitness more than deserting a partner and remating (Grafen and Sibly,
Fathers contribute to their offspring's well-being in a variety of ways. While typically characterized as focused on forms of indirect investment (e.g., resources, calories, protection, monetary investments; Kleiman and Malcolm,
While human fathers participate in indirect and direct investment to varying degrees across human societies, how best to characterize male motivations for investment remains a point of contention (e.g., Gurven and Hill,
While males can choose how to allocate their time, payoffs to a particular behavioral strategy depend on marginal returns to offspring investment (e.g., Hurtado and Hill,
Leveraging data that were collected in a Maya community across two distinct time periods and spanning 20 years (1992 and 2011), we analyze changes in male investment before and after economic development. Traditionally, Maya men spent much of the time outside of the home, away from the village and attending agricultural fields. This limited opportunities for men to engage in childcare and other household activities. An agrarian economy also limits payoffs to concentrated investment in a few children because large families provide agricultural help for food production and foster relational and labor-based wealth (Kramer and Boone,
To examine questions about shifts in paternal investment, we use time allocation data that were collected across two distinct time periods in a remote rural Maya community in the interior of the Yucatan Peninsula, Campeche, Mexico. Economic, demographic, subsistence, and social trends have been studied in this community since 1992. The first sample of behavioral data used in the following analyses was collected during a year-long time allocation study (Kramer,
However, in the mid-2000s, rapid economic development began when a paved road was built linking the community to the regional economy. The road facilitated access to new farming methods, the transportation of crops to market, and people to wage labor jobs. The introduction of tractors and mechanized farming minimized agricultural labor inputs and time spent farming. These changes too expanded the potential for men to pursue different and new subsistence options in and out of the community, which allowed them to generate cash. However, wage labor opportunities were low-paying and temporary and did not allow households to completely transition to a dependency on market jobs. While wage-labor opportunities outside of the village are generally low-skill, parents recognize that education is an important contributing factor for their children to be competitive on this new economic landscape and to secure a well-paying and permanent position in the future. Thus, formal education also has become a priority for most families. To this point, time spent in school among children 6–15 years of age increased by 50% between 1992 and 2011.
While the subsistence economy changed over the 20-year interval, many aspects of reproduction remained the same. During both time periods (1992 and 2011), Maya marriages can be described as life-long and monogamous (Cashdan et al.,
To evaluate how much time Maya fathers invest in their children and how childcare versus provisioning behaviors change before and after economic development, we compare time allocation data from 1992 to 2011. Time budget information is combined with economic and household composition data for the two time periods from databases collected and maintained by KLK. Birth records are used to determine father's and children's ages and are available for both samples. The ages of participants without birth records have been cross checked during multiple annual censuses.
Time allocation data were collected using instantaneous scan sampling techniques. Instantaneous scan sampling is a behavioral observation technique widely used in both non-human animal and human studies to measure the frequency of activities (Washburn and Lancaster,
For both the 1992 and 2011 observation periods, each participant was drawn from the community census and then observed on at least four separate occasions. During those periods, scan samples were recorded, with each observation period lasting ~4 h. An individual's activity and location were recorded at 15 min intervals. The Maya scan data were collected on a subset of the community (112 individuals or 30% of total population in 1992 and 91 individuals or 18% of total population in 2011), which included 15 fathers in each time period whose average ages were not significantly different (mean age is 36.7 years in 1992 and 34 years in 2011). During a scan sample, individuals were located at specific time intervals, with the researcher recording where they were and what they were doing. Over 400 types of activities were coded, which in addition to childcare, included subsistence (foraging, fishing, hunting, fieldwork), domestic (collecting firewood, water, processing food, cooking, sewing, washing), children's play, social, leisure, and hygiene activities. Scan observations primarily occurred in the household. If a person could not be located during a sampling interval, family members were asked about where the individual was and what he or she was doing. Since several hours were spent with a family during each bout, in many cases a person would be observed leaving and then returning with, for example, a load of firewood or a basket of maize, and location and activity information could be confirmed with the participant. The same methods and suite of hierarchical codes were used to record behaviors in 1992 and 2011. Across the two time periods over 25,000 scan samples were recorded, which were culled to paternal observations (
Percentage of time Maya fathers spent in each of four geographically distinct areas in 1992 and 2011.
Within the home a father's time was further categorized into one of three activities: interacting with a child (i.e., direct and indirect childcare), domestic work, or leisure. Direct care (e.g., holding, grooming, carrying, feeding), and indirect care (e.g., helping with homework, disciplining, talking to) were merged into a single childcare category. Domestic work includes food processing and preparation, cleaning, washing, repairing, building, or gardening within the household compound. Leisure was defined as time spent in self-maintenance, bathing, napping, or engaging in social activities with anyone other than a father's children. These suites of activities were then used to calculate the percentage of time fathers engaged in a particular set of behaviors at both time points.
Research protocols and consent procedures were approved by the University of New Mexico's Institutional Review Board (Maya 1992 data) and Harvard University's Institutional Review Board (Maya 2011 data).
To evaluate the role of economic development on paternal involvement in the household and investment in children, we first conduct logistic regression to assess whether fathers time allocation budget were different across the two time periods. The year the data were collected is the predictor variable and paternal presence in a particular geographic sphere is the outcome variable. We then use generalized linear mixed models (GLMM) to explore individual predictors of fathers for their presence/absence in a geographic sphere. Fixed effects include: (1) infant in household (<1 year old), (2) number of children in the household (between 1 and 16 years old), (3) the amount of land under cultivation (in hectares) as a measure of wealth, and 4) father's age. Because each father has multiple observations, random effects for “father” are included to account for the nested structure of the data and associated clustering. Random effects allow for heterogeneity in the outcome by individual and for unbalanced observations per person.
To then evaluate how fathers spend their time at home and whether changes occur in childcare activities, we use logistic regression to assess whether activities within the home differ across the two time periods. The year data were collected is the predictor variable and whether a father was observed interacting with his children, engaged in domestic work, or in leisure are the outcome variables. To explain variation among fathers in how they spend time at home, we apply GLMM, with individual predictors of fathers as fixed effects, individuals as random effects, and paternal presence in a particular activity while at home as the outcome.
Analyses were performed in R [35] using lme4 [36]. Multilevel models, where employed, were selected as the best analytic approach because (1) they are appropriate for nested data; (2) intercepts are allowed to vary by the group-level variable (random effect; father); and (3) fixed effects are shared across all groups. All multilevel models include fixed effects for infant in household, number of children in the household, the amount of land under cultivation, and father's age and random effects for individual.
Following economic development, fathers appear to spend more time at home at the expense of time spent in other areas (Figure
Logistic regression with Year as the predictor and geographic areas as outcomes.
(Intercept) | 0.34 |
0.31–0.38 | 0.13 |
0.11–0.14 | 0.50 |
0.46–0.54 | 0.43 |
0.39–0.47 |
Year | 2.32 |
1.98–2.71 | 0.07 |
0.03–0.13 | 0.84 |
0.71–0.99 | 0.79 |
0.67–0.94 |
Observations | 3189 | 3189 | 3189 | 3189 |
Within each period, we then fit generalized linear mixed models to evaluate which paternal characteristics are associated with the probability of a father being observed in a particular geographic sphere. In 1992, and focusing on our significant results, we find that older fathers and those who have an infant in the home are at increased odds to be observed at home (OR = 1.06 and 4.27 respectively; Table
Generalized linear multilevel logistic regression with traits of fathers as predictors and geographic areas as outcomes for 1992.
(Intercept) | 0.03 |
0.01–0.16 | 0.16 | 0.01–3.10 | 0.04 |
0.01–0.26 | 3.96 | 0.40–39.54 |
Children (#) | 0.77 | 0.58–1.02 | 0.71 | 0.42–1.19 | 0.95 | 0.70–1.29 | 1.24 | 0.82–1.88 |
Age | 1.06 |
1.02–1.10 | 1.00 | 0.93–1.07 | 1.03 | 0.98–1.07 | 0.97 | 0.92–1.03 |
Infant present | 4.27 |
1.55–11.82 | 2.78 | 0.42–18.29 | 1.09 | 0.35–3.36 | 0.46 | 0.10–2.01 |
Cultivated Land | 1.02 | 0.78–1.33 | 1.05 | 0.65–1.68 | 1.86 |
1.38–2.49 | 0.53 |
0.36–0.78 |
NID | 15 | 15 | 15 | 15 | ||||
ICCID | 0.087 | 0.251 | 0.105 | 0.182 | ||||
Observations | 2194 | 2194 | 2194 | 2194 |
Generalized linear multilevel logistic regression with traits of fathers as predictors and geographic areas as outcomes for 2011.
(Intercept) | 0.86 | 0.13–5.82 | 472.70 | 0.02–12338856.50 | 1.90 | 0.11–33.42 | 0.11 | 0.00–4.79 |
Children (#) | 0.78 | 0.60–1.02 | 0.42 | 0.16–1.08 | 0.83 | 0.58–1.18 | 1.75 |
1.04–2.94 |
Age | 1.00 | 0.96–1.04 | 0.80 |
0.65–0.98 | 0.98 | 0.92–1.04 | 1.00 | 0.92–1.08 |
Infant present | 1.28 | 0.53–3.07 | 0.01 |
0.00–0.67 | 0.26 |
0.07–0.95 | 1.78 | 0.33–9.50 |
Cultivated Land | 1.15 | 0.97–1.37 | 1.09 | 0.68–1.74 | 1.05 | 0.83–1.32 | 0.73 | 0.52–1.03 |
NID | 15 | 15 | 15 | 15 | ||||
ICCID | 0.091 | 0.000 | 0.164 | 0.301 | ||||
Observations | 995 | 995 | 995 | 995 |
We then ask, when fathers are at home, what are they doing (Figure
Percentage of time Maya fathers spend in different activities while in the home.
Logistic regression with Year as the predictor and activities within home sphere as outcomes.
(Intercept) | 0.24 |
0.20–0.30 | 0.50 |
0.42–0.59 | 0.69 |
0.59–0.82 |
Year | 1.45 |
1.08–1.94 | 0.59 |
0.45–0.78 | 1.35 |
1.06–1.74 |
Observations | 1021 | 1021 | 1021 |
We then assess the role of fathers' individual traits in predicting how a father spends his time while at home. In 1992, fathers with more children under the age of 16 are at increased odds to be observed in domestic work (OR = 1.35) and at decreased odds to be observed in leisure (OR = 0.64). Odds to be observed at leisure, however, increases with age (OR = 1.04) and if the father has an infant in the home (OR = 4.50; Table
Generalized linear multilevel logistic regression with traits of fathers as predictors and activities at home as outcomes for 1992.
(Intercept) | 0.43 | 0.13–1.47 | 0.18 |
0.04–0.87 | 1.24 | 0.35–4.39 |
Children (#) | 1.35 |
1.11–1.65 | 0.64 |
0.51–0.81 | 0.51–0.81 | 0.89–1.33 |
Age | 0.97 | 0.95–1.00 | 1.04 |
1.00–1.07 | 0.99 | 0.96–1.02 |
Infant present | 0.37 |
0.17–0.85 | 4.50 |
1.70–11.97 | 0.74 | 0.33–1.68 |
Cultivated Land | 0.98 | 0.77–1.25 | 1.06 | 0.80–1.41 | 0.84 | 0.66–1.06 |
NID | 15 | 15 | 15 | |||
ICCID | 0.000 | 0.028 | 0.018 | |||
Observations | 561 | 561 | 561 |
Generalized linear multilevel logistic regression with traits of fathers as predictors and activities at home as outcomes for 2011.
(Intercept) | 0.01 |
0.00–0.24 | 0.43 | 0.09–2.01 | 2.16 | 0.18–25.84 |
Children (#) | 1.00 | 0.68–1.48 | 1.08 | 0.87–1.34 | 0.92 | 0.65–1.30 |
Age | 0.99 | 0.93–1.05 | 1.02 | 0.99–1.06 | 1.02 | 0.97–1.07 |
Infant present | 5.57 |
1.47–21.12 | 0.75 | 0.37–1.54 | 0.38 | 0.12–1.20 |
Cultivated Land | 1.99 |
1.50–2.65 | 0.71 |
0.62–0.82 | 0.79 |
0.64–0.99 |
NID | 15 | 15 | 15 | |||
ICCID | 0.118 | 0.009 | 0.126 |
In summary, we report seven key findings of relevance to male paternal investment behaviors. After the introduction of economic development, which facilitated access to urban markets and alternative ways to allocate time, fathers spend: (1) more time at home; (2) less time in their agricultural fields and out of town: (3) less time in social activities with other men in the village, particularly when they have an infant in the home; (4) more time interacting with their children (5) more time in domestic work; (6) less time in leisure; and (7) an increasing amount of time out of town in response to more children in the home.
Paternal investment can range from genetic inheritance (Savalli and Fox,
For this project, we leveraged insight from life history theory as well as research on paternal investment in industrialized populations. Now that Maya fathers have their time open to other pursuits, what do they do with this found time? We predicted that in response to economic development and a transition to a skills-based and education dependent economy, fathers would devote a greater proportion of their time budget to the needs of their children. Economic development and a market-based economy have been shown to incentivize intense investment in children, both in terms of indirect and direct investment (Pleck,
The complementary nature of the division of labor as well as normatively enforced monogamy among the Maya results in few investment options outside of the pair-bond for men. Marriage to a single partner is the avenue toward adulthood, household formation, and the production of children. Over the 20-year period considered here, divorce and out of wedlock birth have never been reported. Thus, generalizing from this case study, we would predict that, in a monogamous population with few opportunities for males to earn fitness benefits through other means, when opportunities arise to augment offspring quality, fathers will respond by intensifying investment in their children.
Monogamy describes the Maya mating pattern, however, sexual exclusivity within marriage is not a human universal, neither for men nor women (Neel,
While the nuclear family (i.e., mother, father, and dependent children as a self-contained economic entity) is often thought to be the fundamental human unit, this family structure is typical of industrialized rather than small-scale societies. It is well documented that the human family exhibits remarkable flexibility within and across populations and social organization typical of cooperative breeders (Hrdy,
Economic development across a broad swath of small-scale societies is currently occurring very rapidly. However, we do not expect outcomes to be uniform across place. Optimal levels of paternal investment are expected to vary by socioecological factors, including subsistence type, social organization, and mating system. The changes in paternal investment documented here are largely contingent on four conditions: increased efficiency in subsistence brought about by mechanized farming, limited opportunities to engage in wage labor, increased opportunities to invest in offspring quality, and a monogamous mating system. Because males can choose how to allocate their time, payoffs to a particular strategy are expected to be sensitive to marginal returns to offspring investment. Fathers with additional time on their hands as a consequence of mechanized farming are not universally expected to invest more in their children. This time could be reallocated to mating effort, leisure, socializing, or in a number of other ways. However, among the Maya, as a consequence of monogamous marriage and a transition to a skills-based economy, fathers are directing “found time” to their children. In other small-scale societies, economic development in contrast has opened up opportunities for fathers to work outside of the community, which has led to fathers to adopt market jobs as opportunities to provision the family, and thus spend more time away from their children (Mattison et al.,
While behavioral observation and time allocation data are a “gold-standard” in the study of behavior, this approach also has limitations. Because of the intensive time investment required for data collection, the sample of fathers for both time periods is small, potentially giving only a partial view of paternal behavior. To minimize bias, fathers included in the study were drawn from a community-wide census. One source of bias that we were not able to account for was migration-bias. Our data come from men who have chosen to remain in the community, which may select for particular kinds of men. And while not a limitation
Percentage of time Maya mothers spent in each of four geographically distinct areas in 1992 and 2011.
Maternal investment is necessary for infants and young children to survive in all but the most modern of human societies (Kramer,
The coauthors collectively conceived the idea and edited the manuscript. RS and KK wrote the manuscript. KK collected the data, HD created the database, and RS performed the analyses.
The authors declare that the research was conducted in the absence of any commercial or financial relationships that could be construed as a potential conflict of interest.